Skip to main content
Log in

Is the Retail Gasoline Market Local or National?

  • Published:
Journal of Industry, Competition and Trade Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper studies the effect of station density on prices in the retail gasoline market in the Czech Republic. We estimate the impact of the number of competing stations in various driving-distance ranges around each station on prices. We find that station density has a negative effect on prices; the effect decreases with distance and is statistically significant up to six kilometers. This suggests that the retail gasoline market is local rather than national.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. https://www.fuelseurope.eu/uploads/Modules/Dataroom/fuelseurope_graph_2015-50.pdf

  2. The application is available both for Android and iOS. Google claims that it has been downloaded more than 100,000 times (the published range is from 100,000 to 500,000) on February 2015. The application’s official web page is http://www.pumpdroid.com/.

  3. For most stations, the price data is almost complete or complete. E.g. in October 2014, 81 % of stations (with at least one price observation in this month) had more than 20 price observations. Most of these prices are reported by the stations or chains. In the remaining cases, the data comes from Pumpdroid users who are motivated to submit new information about prices only after the price changes. This means that there are gaps in time series of these stations. However, these gaps have no economic consequences because the price stays the same when the data are missing. For this reason, we fill in the missing data with the last available price information when computing the price averages.

References

  • Barron J M, Taylor B A, Umbeck J R (2004) Number of sellers, average prices, and price dispersion. Int J Ind Organ 22(8):1041–1066

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chouinard H H, Perloff J M (2007) Gasoline price differences: taxes, pollution regulations, mergers, market power, and market conditions. The BE J Econ Anal Policy 7(1)

  • Clemenz G, Gugler K (2006) Locational choice and price competition: some empirical results for the Austrian retail gasoline market. Empir Econ 31(2):291–312

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cooper T E, Jones J T (2007) Asymmetric competition on commuter routes: the case of gasoline pricing. South Econ J:483–504

  • Eckert A, West D S (2004) A tale of two cities: Price uniformity and price volatility in gasoline retailing. Ann Reg Sci 38(1):25–46

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hastings J S (2004) Vertical relationships and competition in retail gasoline markets: Empirical evidence from contract changes in southern california. Am Econ Rev 94 (1):317–328

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hosken D S, McMillan R S, Taylor C T (2008) Retail gasoline pricing: What do we know? Int J Ind Organ 26(6):1425–1436

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Houde J F (2012) Spatial differentiation and vertical mergers in retail markets for gasoline. Am Econ Rev 102(5):2147–2182

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kihm A, Ritter N, Vance C (2016) Is the german retail gasoline market competitive? a spatial-temporal analysis using quantile regression. Land Econ 92 (4):718–736

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pennerstorfer D (2009) Spatial price competition in retail gasoline markets: evidence from Austria. Ann Reg Sci 43(1):133–158

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pennerstorfer D, Weiss C (2013) Spatial clustering and market power: Evidence from the retail gasoline market. Reg Sci Urban Econ 43(4):661–675

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sen A (2003) Higher prices at canadian gas pumps: international crude oil prices or local market concentration? an empirical investigation. Energy Econ 25(3):269–288

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sen A (2005) Does increasing the market share of smaller firms result in lower prices? empirical evidence from the canadian retail gasoline industry. Rev Ind Organ 26(4):371–389

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shepard A (1993) Contractual form, retail price, and asset characteristics in gasoline retailing. RAND J Econ 24(1):58–77

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simpson J, Taylor C (2008) Do gasoline mergers affect consumer prices? the marathon ashland petroleum and ultramar diamond shamrock transaction. J Law Econ 51(1):135–152

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Taylor C T, Hosken D S (2007) The economic effects of the marathon-ashland joint venture: The importance of industry supply shocks and vertical market structure. J Ind Econ 55(3):419–451

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van Meerbeeck W (2003) Competition and local market conditions on the belgian retail gasoline market. De Economist 151(4):369–388

Download references

Acknowledgments

We thank Mr. Marcel Matula of Pumpdroid for kindly providing us with the data.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Ondřej Krčál.

Appendix A: Modeling the effects of station density

Appendix A: Modeling the effects of station density

The model has a structure of M spokes. Each spoke has a length d i . There are N+1 firms, where NM. Firms have a constant marginal cost c. Firm 0 is located at the center; N firms are located at the extremes of N spokes. Firms are indexed such that firm i is located at the extreme of spoke i. There is a continuum of consumers with mass 1. The mass of consumers which are uniformly distributed along each spoke is 1/M. So, the distribution function of consumers along spoke i is 1/(M d i ).

The consumers behave in the same way as in the Hotelling model. Each consumer buys one unit of goods; the preferences can be described by the utility function U = RpT x, where R is the reservation price; p is the price to be paid; T are the transportation costs; and x is the distance to the firm. The demand for the production of firm 0 along the spoke is given as follows

  • \(D_{0}=\frac {R-p_{0}}{T}\) if there is no competitor.

  • \(D_{0}=\frac {1}{2}+\frac {p_{i}-p_{0}}{2d_{i}T}\) if there is a competitor.

The profit of firm 0 is

$${\Pi}_0=\frac{M-N}{M}(p_0-c)\frac{R-p_0}{T}+\frac{1}{M} \sum\limits_{i=1}^N (p_0-c) \left( \frac{1}{2}+\frac{p_i-p_0}{2d_iT} \right) $$

The profit of firm \(i \in \{1,\dots ,N \}\) is

$${\Pi}_i=(p_i-c) \left( \frac{1}{2}+\frac{p_0-p_i}{2d_iT} \right)$$

We derive best-response functions and solve for the equilibrium price \(p_{0}^{*}\). The equilibrium price \(p_{0}^{*}\) is implicitly given by the following equation.

$$ (M-N)(R-2p_{0}^{*}+c)+ \sum\limits_{i=1}^{N} \left( \frac{3T}{4}-\frac{ p_{0}^{*}-c}{4d_{i}} \right)=0 $$
(2)

Suppose without loss of generality that there are N 1 firms at a distance d 1 from the center, N 2 firms in distance d 2 from the center, and so on. Of course, it holds that \(N_{1}+N_{2}+\dots +N_{k}=N\). The distances are indexed such that \(d_{1}<d_{2}<\dots <d_{k}\).

By differentiating the Eq. 2 according to N i we can express how the equilibrium price depends on the number of firms at a distance d i :

$$ -R+2p_{0}^{*}-c+\frac{3T}{4}-\frac{ p_{0}^{*}-c}{4d_{i}}=\frac{\partial p_{0}^{*}}{\partial N_{i}} \left( 2(M-N)+\frac{1}{4} \left( \frac{N_{1}}{d_{1}}+\dots+ \frac{N_{k}}{d_{k}} \right) \right) $$
(3)

It follows from the condition (2) that the left-hand side of the equation is negative. The second term on the right-hand side is positive. Hence, we may conclude that if you increase the number of firms at any distance level d i , the price of firm 0 falls:

$$\frac{\partial p_0^*}{\partial N_i}<0$$

Suppose that d i <d j . We want to compare \(\frac {\partial p_{0}^{*}}{\partial N_{i}}\) and \(\frac {\partial p_{0}^{*}}{\partial N_{j}}\), i.e. what happens with the price if we add a competitor at a distance d i or at a distance d j . The comparison of these two effects depends only on the left-hand side of Eq. 3 because the second term on the right-hand side is the same for both. Obviously, the absolute value of the left-hand side is decreasing in d i . Therefore it follows that if we increase the number of firms at a lower distance d i <d j , the price of firm 0 falls more:

$$\left| \frac{\partial p_0^*}{\partial N_i} \right| > \left| \frac{\partial p_0^*}{\partial N_j} \right|$$

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Kvasnička, M., Staněk, R. & Krčál, O. Is the Retail Gasoline Market Local or National?. J Ind Compet Trade 18, 47–58 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10842-017-0249-0

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Revised:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10842-017-0249-0

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation