H. Parr, ‘Gone Native: The Foreign Office and Harold Wilson’s Policy towards the EEC, 1964–67’, in O. J. Daddow (ed.), Harold Wilson and European Integration: Britain’s Second Application to Join the EEC (London, 2003), p. 82. Parr also suggests that ‘Wilson’s decision to embark on the initiative [for EEC membership] was not the result of Foreign Offce pressure, but of the shock of the 1966 July sterling crisis’ (ibid., p. 89).
Google Scholar
B. Pimlott, Harold Wilson (London, 1993), pp. 432, 435.
Google Scholar
H. Wilson, The Labour Government 1964–1970: A Personal Record (London, 1971), pp. 2–3.
Google Scholar
Britain’s share of world trade in manufactures had fallen from about 25 per cent in 1949 to 12 per cent in 1967. See A. Cairncross and B. Eichengreen, Sterling in Decline: The Devaluations of 1931, 1949 and 1967 (Oxford, 1983), p. 219.
Google Scholar
P. Catterall, ‘Foreign and Commonwealth Policy in Opposition: The Labour Party’, in W. Kaiser and G. Staerck (eds.), British Foreign Policy, 1955–64. Contracting Options (Basingstoke, 2000), p. 102.
Google Scholar
Labour Party, Foreign Policy and Defence (London, 1960), p. 1, cited in Catterall, ‘Foreign and Commonwealth Policy in Opposition’, p. 94.
Google Scholar
M. Daunton, ‘From Bretton Woods to Havana: Multilateral Deadlocks in Historical Perspective’, in A. Narliker (ed.), Deadlocks in Multilateral Negotiations: Causes and Solutions (Cambridge, 2010), p. 64.
Google Scholar
J. Darwin, The End of the British Empire: The Historical Debate (Oxford, 1991), p. 46.
Google Scholar
J. Darwin, ‘Between Europe and Empire: Britain’s Changing Role in World Politics since 1945’, in A. M. Birke, M. Brechtken and A. Searle (eds.), An Anglo-German Dialogue: The Munich Lectures on the History of International Relations (Munich, 2000), p. 209.
Google Scholar
B. Castle, Fighting All the Way (London, 1993), p. 380.
Google Scholar
C. King, The Cecil King Diary 1965–1970 (London, 1972), p. 95.
Google Scholar
A. Morgan, Harold Wilson (London, 1992), p. 290.
Google Scholar
B. Castle, The Castle Diaries 1964–70 (London, 1974), p. 147.
Google Scholar
B. Tew, ‘Onwards to EMU’, in D. Swann (ed.), The Single European Market and Beyond: A Study of Wider Implications of the Single European Act (London, 1992), p. 193.
Google Scholar
J. Darwin, Britain and Decolonisation: The Retreat from Empire in the Post-War World (London, 1988), p. 291.
CrossRef
Google Scholar
See John Dumbrell, ‘The Johnson Administration and the British Labour Government: Vietnam, the Pound and East of Suez’, Journal of American Studies, Vol. 30, No. 2, Part 2 (August 1996), p. 227.
CrossRef
Google Scholar
In August and September 1965, George Ball (US Undersecretary of State) and Henry Fowler (US Secretary of the Treasury) travelled around Europe in order to secure short-term facilities of $925 million, to which the United States contributed $400 million. These facilities were available for three months, except the facility with the United States, which had no terminal date. See J. Fielding, ‘Coping with Decline: US Policy toward the British Defence Reviews of 1966’, Diplomatic History, Vol. 23, No. 4 (Fall 1999), p. 645. BOE EID 1/24, ‘A History of the Sterling Crisis’, Appendix I, p. 3.
CrossRef
Google Scholar
R. H. S. Crossman, Diaries of a Cabinet Member, Volume 1 (London, 1975), p. 539.
Google Scholar
Pimlott, Harold Wilson, p. 273. Pimlott relies on the analysis of Perry Anderson, an articulate theoretician of the New Left. See, P. Anderson, ‘Critique of Wilsonism’, New Left Review, Vol. 27 (1964), pp. 3–27.
Google Scholar
J. S. Odell, U.S. International Monetary Policy: Markets, Power, and Ideas as Sources of Change (Princeton, NJ, 1982), p. 130.
Google Scholar
S. D. Cohen, International Monetary Reform, 1964–69: The Political Dimension (New York, 1970), p. 63, emphasis in the original.
Google Scholar
Thompson-McCausland suggested that: ‘The new plan [for SDRs] passes no judgment on whether there is now a shortage of assets or not.’ See L. P. Thompson-McCausland, ‘The Place of Special Drawing Rights in the International Monetary System’, BOE Quarterly Bulletin, Vol. 8, No. 2 (1968), p. 147.
Google Scholar
It is pertinent to refer here to the difference of status as economic adviser between them. After Wilson became Prime Minster in 1964, Balogh became Economic Adviser on Economic Affairs to the Cabinet, with special reference to external economic policy. Kaldor was Special Adviser to the Chancellor of the Exchequer on the Social and Economic Aspects of Taxation Policy. In other words, Balogh was adviser to Wilson and attached to the Cabinet, whereas Kaldor was adviser to Callaghan and attached to the Treasury and seconded to the Inland Revenue. Kaldor’s work as economic adviser concentrated on two areas: balance of payments and taxation. See P. Arestis and M. C. Sawyer (eds.), A Biographical Dictionary of Dissenting Economists (Cheltenham, 2000), pp. 14–21 (Thomas Balogh), pp. 293–302 (Nicholas Kaldor); J. E. King, Nicholas Kaldor (Basingstoke, 2009), pp. 96–9; A. P. Thirlwall, Nicholas Kaldor (Sussex, 1987), pp. 229–57; F. Targetti, Nicholas Kaldor: The Economics and Politics of Capitalism as a Dynamic System (Oxford, 1992), pp. 20–4.
Google Scholar