Skip to main content

Abstract

Conservatives need Charles Darwin. They need him because a Darwinian science of human nature supports the conservative commitment to liberty as rooted in nature, custom, and reason. The intellectual vitality of conservatism in the twenty-first century will depend upon the success of conservatives in appealing to advances in the biology of human nature as confirming conservative social thought.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 39.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Notes

  1. For elaboration of my reasoning, see Larry Arnhart, Darwinian Conservatism (Exeter, UK: Imprint Academic, 2005).

    Google Scholar 

  2. For criticisms of my reasoning, see Carson Holloway, The Right Darwin? (Dallas: Spence Publishing, 2006);

    Google Scholar 

  3. and John G. West, Darwin’s Conservatives: The Misguided Quest (Seattle: Discovery Institute Press, 2006).

    Google Scholar 

  4. Michael Polanyi, The Logic of Liberty: Reflections and Rejoinders (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1951), pp. 154–178;

    Google Scholar 

  5. Friedrich A. Hayek, The Constitution of Liberty (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1960), pp. 159–161.

    Google Scholar 

  6. Ronald Hamowy, The Scottish Enlightenment and the Theory of Spontaneous Order (Carbondale: Southern Illinois University Press, 1987).

    Google Scholar 

  7. Friedrich A. Hayek, Law, Legislation and Liberty, vol. 1, Rules and Order (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1973), pp. 22–23.

    Google Scholar 

  8. Alan Ebenstein, Hayek’s Journey: The Mind of Friedrich Hayek (New York: Palgrave Macmillan, 2003), p. 6.

    Google Scholar 

  9. I have defended Darwinian evolution in debates with Michael Behe, William Dembski, and other conservative proponents of “intelligent design.” See Larry Arnhart, “Conservatives, Darwin, and Design,” First Things, 107 (November 2000): 23–31; “Evolution and the New Creationism,” Skeptic 8, no. 4 (2001): 46–52; and “Assault on Evolution,” Salon.com, February 28, 2001, www.salon.com/books/feature/2001/02/28/idt/print.html.

    Google Scholar 

  10. Hayek, Constitution, pp. 54–70; Thomas Sowell, A Conflict of Visions: Ideological Origins of Political Struggles (New York: Basic Books, 2002).

    Google Scholar 

  11. Steven Pinker, The Blank Slate: The Modern Denial of Human Nature (New York: Viking, 2002), pp. 283–305.

    Google Scholar 

  12. Ludwig von Mises, Socialism: An Economic and Sociological Analysis, trans. J. Kahane (Indianapolis: Liberty Classics, 1981), pp. 87, 157.

    Google Scholar 

  13. Paul Rubin, Darwinian Politics: The Evolutionary Origins of Freedom (New Brunswick, NJ: Rutgers University Press, 2002).

    Google Scholar 

  14. Peter Singer, A Darwinian Left: Politics, Evolution and Cooperation (New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, 1999).

    Google Scholar 

  15. James Bernard Murphy provides the best account of this trichotomy of order in his book The Moral Economy of Labor: Aristotelian Themes in Economic Theory (New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, 1993) and in “Nature, Custom, and Reason as the Explanatory and Practical Principles of Aristotelian Political Science,” The Review of Politics 64 (2002): 469–495. See also Larry Arnhart, Aristotle on Political Reasoning: A Commentary on the “Rhetoric” (DeKalb: Northern Illinois University, 1981), pp. 102–105; Political Questions: Political Philosophy from Plato to Rawls, 3rd ed. (Prospect Heights, IL: Waveland Press, 2003), pp. 97–98.

    Google Scholar 

  16. Charles Darwin, The Descent of Man, and Selection in Relation to Sex, 2 vols. (London: J. Murray, 1871), 1: 70–106, 158–167; 2: 390–394.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  17. David Ritchie, Darwinism and Politics (New York: Charles Scribner’s Sons, 1901), pp. 6–7, 42–49.

    Google Scholar 

  18. For examples of coevolutionary theory, see Edward O. Wilson, Consilience: The Unity of Knowledge (New York: Knopf, 1998);

    Google Scholar 

  19. and Peter J. Richerson and Robert Boyd, Not by Genes Alone: How Culture Transformed Human Evolution (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2005).

    Google Scholar 

  20. Friedrich A. Hayek, Law, Legislation and Liberty, vol. 3, The Political Order of a Free People (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1979), pp. xi, 153–176.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  21. See Ronald Hamowy, “F. A. Hayek and the Common Law,” The Cato Journal, 23 (Fall 2003): 241–264.

    Google Scholar 

  22. For elaboration of this point, see James Bernard Murphy, “Nature, Custom, and Stipulation in Law and Jurisprudence,” Review of Metaphysics 43 (June 1990): 751–790.

    Google Scholar 

  23. See Adam Smith, The Theory of Moral Sentiments (Indianapolis: Liberty Classics, 1982), pp. 77, 87, 142;

    Google Scholar 

  24. and David Hume, “Dialogues Concerning Natural Religion,” in Writings on Religion, ed. Antony Flew (La Salle, IL: Open Court, 1992), pp. 228–229, 240–242, 246–247.

    Google Scholar 

  25. See Larry Arnhart, Darwinian Natural Right: The Biological Ethics of Human Nature (Albany: State University of New York Press, 1998), pp. 36–44, 56–58;

    Google Scholar 

  26. John T. Bonner, The Evolution of Culture in Animals (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1980);

    Google Scholar 

  27. and Frans de Waal, The Apes and the Sushi Master (New York: Basic Books, 2001).

    Google Scholar 

  28. See A. Whiten et al., “Cultures in Chimpanzees,” Nature 399 (1999): 682–685;

    Article  Google Scholar 

  29. William C. McGrew, The Cultured Chimpanzee: Reflections on Cultural Primatology (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2004).

    Book  Google Scholar 

  30. See, for example, Antonio Damasio, Descartes’s Error: Emotion, Reason, and the Human Brain (New York: G. P. Putnam’s Sons, 1994);

    Google Scholar 

  31. and Michael S. Gazzaniga, Richard B. Ivry, and George R. Mangun, Cognitive Neuroscience: The Biology of the Mind, 2nd ed. (New York: Norton, 2002), pp. 445–576.

    Google Scholar 

  32. See Paul Glimcher, Decisions, Uncertainty, and the Brain: The Science of Neuroeconomics (Cambridge: MIT Press, 2003).

    Google Scholar 

  33. Friedrich A. Hayek, The Sensory Order (Chicago: University of Chicago, 1952).

    Google Scholar 

  34. See Donald Brown, Human Universals (Philadelphia: Temple University Press, 1991); and Pinker, Blank Slate, pp. 435–439.

    Google Scholar 

  35. See Edward Westermarck, The Origin and Development of the Moral Ideas, 2 vols. (London: Macmillan, 1908), 2: 1–71; and Brown, Human Universals, pp. 139–140.

    Google Scholar 

  36. Richard Pipes, Property and Freedom (New York: Alfred A. Knopf, 1999), pp. 65–88.

    Google Scholar 

  37. Adam Smith, An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, 2 vols., eds. R. H. Campbell and A. S. Skinner (Indianapolis: Liberty Fund, 1981), 1: 25.

    Google Scholar 

  38. See Haim Ofek, Second Nature: Economic Origins of Human Evolution (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2001).

    Book  Google Scholar 

  39. See Bruce L. Benson, The Enterprise of Law: Justice without the State (San Francisco, CA: Pacific Research Institute for Public Policy, 1990), pp. 11–36; and “Customary Law as a Social Contract: International Commercial Law,” Constitutional Political Economy 3 (1992): 1–27.

    Google Scholar 

  40. See Hernando de Soto, The Mystery of Capital: Why Capitalism Triumphs in the West and Fails Everywhere Else (New York: Basic Books, 2000).

    Google Scholar 

  41. Friedrich Hayek, “Origins and Effects of Our Morals,” in The Essence of Hayek, eds. Chiaki Nishiyama and Kurt R. Leube, (Stanford, CA: Hoover Institution Press, 1984), pp. 318–330.

    Google Scholar 

  42. Hayek, Individualism and Economic Order (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1948), pp. 22–23.

    Google Scholar 

  43. See Arnhart, “Thomistic Natural Law as Darwinian Natural Right”; and “The Incest Taboo as Darwinian Natural Right,” in Incest, Inbreeding, and the Westermarck Effect, ed. Arthur Wolf and William Durham, (Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press, 2004), pp. 190–218.

    Google Scholar 

  44. See Martin Ottenheimer, Forbidden Relatives: The American Myth of Cousin Marriage (Urbana: University of Illinois Press, 1996).

    Google Scholar 

  45. See Gary Johnson, “The Evolutionary Origins of Government and Politics,” in Human Nature and Politics, ed. Joseph Losco and Albert Somit (Greenwich, CT: JAI Press, 1995), pp. 243–305.

    Google Scholar 

  46. See Steven Goldberg, Why Men Rule: A Theory of Male Dominance (LaSalle, IL: Open Court, 1993);

    Google Scholar 

  47. and Arnold Ludwig, King of the Mountain: The Nature of Political Leadership (Lexington: University Press of Kentucky, 2002).

    Google Scholar 

  48. See, for example, Pinker, Blank Slate, 283–305; Mark F. Grady and Michael T. McGuire, “The Nature of Constitutions,” Journal of Bioeconomics 1 (1999): 227–240;

    Article  Google Scholar 

  49. and Paul H. Rubin, Darwinian Politics: The Evolutionary Origin of Freedom (New Brunswick, NJ: Rutgers University Press, 2002).

    Google Scholar 

  50. Alexander Hamilton, James Madison, and John Jay, The Federalist Papers, No. 51 (New York: Random House, Modern Library, 1937), 337–339.

    Google Scholar 

  51. See George Anastaplo, The Constitution of 1787: A Commentary (Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1989), 1–12;

    Google Scholar 

  52. and Donald S. Lutz, The Origins of American Constitutionalism (Baton Rouge: Louisiana State University Press, 1988).

    Google Scholar 

  53. See Charles Thach, The Creation of the Presidency, 1775–1789 (Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1969).

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Authors

Editor information

Louis Hunt Peter McNamara

Copyright information

© 2007 Louis Hunt and Peter McNamara

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Arnhart, L. (2007). Friedrich Hayek’s Darwinian Conservatism. In: Hunt, L., McNamara, P. (eds) Liberalism, Conservatism, and Hayek’s Idea of Spontaneous Order. Palgrave Macmillan, New York. https://doi.org/10.1057/9780230609228_7

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics