Advertisement

Belarus: Prototype for Market Socialism?

  • Mario Nuti
Part of the Studies in Economic Transition book series (SET)

Abstract

Following the break-up of the Soviet Union in December 1991, Russia on 2 January 1992 liberalized most prices, raising them by a large multiple to equilibrium level. This unilateral move forced all other FSU [former Soviet Union] republics to follow Russia, in order to avoid an accelerated drainage of their goods supply towards Russia and those other republics where they fetched highly inflated, liberalized, rouble prices. Russian monopoly of rouble currency issue caused a generalized cash scarcity in other FSU republics and forced them to issue bank-money, which they could still use in settlement of transactions with Russia. But the Russian Gosbank first in June 1992 set a ceiling to these republican issues of non-cash roubles, then disowned them outright. The other republics were forced to transform the republican subsidiaries of Gosbank into proper republican Central Banks, and to issue first their own rouble substitutes then their own republican currency. If the split of the rouble area had preceded Russian price liberalization in an orderly fashion, instead of following it chaotically, the republics could have chosen from the beginning their own independent monetary policy and inflation path. As it happened each republic received an initial inflationary shock from Russian inflation, before following its own macroeconomic path. Monetary disintegration, both within the FSU rouble area and — officially from September 1991 but in practice from early 1991 — within the Comecon (Council of Mutual Economic Assistance or CMEA) transferable rouble area, disrupted traditional trade flows between FSU republics, and any residual form of planned trade between Comecon partners, exposing state enterprises to market forces.

Keywords

Corporate Governance Foreign Trade Transition Economy Exchange Rate Regime State Enterprise 
These keywords were added by machine and not by the authors. This process is experimental and the keywords may be updated as the learning algorithm improves.

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Notes

  1. 2.
    Elean A. Korosteleva, Colin W. Lawson and Rosalind Marsh (eds). Contemporary Belarus: Between Democracy and Dictatorship (London and New York: RoutledgeCurzon, 2003)Google Scholar
  2. 3.
    Andrew Wilson, ‘The East Europeans: Ukraine, Belarus and Moldova’, in S. White, Judy Batt and Paul Lewis (eds), Developments in Central and East European Politics, Vol. 4 (Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan/Duke UP, 2007).Google Scholar
  3. 6.
    See John Odling-Smee, Monetary Union between Belarus and Russia: an IMF Perspective (Washington, DC: IMF, 2003)Google Scholar
  4. 8.
    See Mario D. Nuti, ‘Making Sense of the Third Way’, Business Strategy Review, 10, 3 (Autumn 1999) 57–67.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. 9.
    Islam Karimov, Building the Future: Uzbekistan — Its Own Model for Transition to a Market Economy (Tashkent: Uzbekistan Publishers, 1993).Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Mario Nuti 2007

Authors and Affiliations

  • Mario Nuti

There are no affiliations available

Personalised recommendations