Skip to main content

The Atlantic Reaction

  • Chapter
Means and Ends
  • 63 Accesses

Abstract

The academic economists of the second half of the nineteenth century rarely took on Marx directly, and they certainly did not consider him as an equal interlocutor. In order to engage in debate with the awkward colleague from a distance what was needed was a free spirit like Thorstein Veblen,1 or a gifted polemist like Eugen Böhm-Bawerk (who we will meet in the next chapter [pp. 128–133]). However, in view of the enormous stir that the Capital caused, no author could ignore him. Marx was at once a social scientist and a revolutionary: thus there was concern over the hold his doctrines were having on public opinion, rather than over the destabilizing potential of his economic theory. This was all the more so when, 13 years after the First International (1864–1876) had been dissolved, there came a second, during which the Marxist fringe clearly predominated over the other currents.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

eBook
USD 16.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 119.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 119.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Notes

  1. T. Veblen, ‘The Socialist Economics of Karl Marx and His Followers I: The Theories of Karl Marx’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 20.4 (1906), pp. 575–595.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  2. I.H. Rima, Development of Economic Analysis (London: Routledge, 2001), p. 274.

    Google Scholar 

  3. N.W. Senior, An Outline of the Science of Political Economy (New York: Kelley, 1965 [1836]), see Introduction;

    Google Scholar 

  4. J.S. Mill, Essays on Some Unsettled Questions of Political Economy [1844], in The Collected Works of John Stuart Mill, vol. IV (London: Routledge & Kegan Paul, 1967), pp. 309ff.

    Google Scholar 

  5. F.M.L. Thompson, The Rise of Respectable Society: A Social History of Victorian Britain 1830–1900 (Cambridge MA: Harvard University Press, 1988);

    Google Scholar 

  6. E.M. Sigsworth (ed.), In Search of Victorian Values: Aspects of Nineteenth-Century Thought and Society (Manchester: Manchester University Press, 1988);

    Google Scholar 

  7. T.C. Smout (ed.), Victorian Values (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1993);

    Google Scholar 

  8. G. Marsden, Victorian Values: Personalities and Perspectives in Nineteenth-Century Society (London: Longman, 1998);

    Google Scholar 

  9. P. Mandler (ed.), Liberty and Authority in Victorian Britain (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2006), particularly Part IV.

    Google Scholar 

  10. G. Crossick, The Lower Middle Class in Britain 1870–1914 (London: Croom Helm, 1977);

    Google Scholar 

  11. S. Gunn, The Public Culture of the Victorian Middle Class: Ritual and Authority in the English Industrial City 1840–1914 (Manchester: Manchester University Press, 2000);

    Google Scholar 

  12. A. Kidd and D. Nicholls (eds), The Making of the British Middle Class? Studies of Regional and Cultural Diversity since the Eighteenth Century (Stroud: Sutton, 1998);

    Google Scholar 

  13. A. Kidd and D. Nicholls (eds), Gender, Civic Culture and Consumerism: Middle-Class Identity in Britain 1800–1940 (Manchester: Manchester University Press, 1999).

    Google Scholar 

  14. J.F.C. Harrison, Late Victorian Britain 1875–1901 (London: Fontana, 1990).

    Google Scholar 

  15. Cf. M. Daunton (ed.), The Cambridge Urban History of Britain, vol. III, 1840— 1950 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2000), pp. 565, 614ff.

    Google Scholar 

  16. S. Smiles, Self-Help; With Illustrations of Character, Conduct, and Perseverance (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2002 [1859]).

    Google Scholar 

  17. Defined in the first edition of the Principles as a ‘mild form of robbery’, which penalized the most industrious individuals ‘for having worked harder and saved more than their neighbours’ Q.S. Mill, Principles of Political Economy with Some of Their Applications to Social Philosophy [variorum edn, 1st edn 1848], ed. by J.M. Robson, in The Collected Works of John Stuart Mill, vols II–III (London: Routledge & Kegan Paul, 1965), p. 811 and footnote k).

    Google Scholar 

  18. See D. Loftus, ‘The Self-Made Man: Businessmen and their Autobiographies in Nineteenth Century Britain’, Business Archives, 80 (2000), pp. 15–30.

    Google Scholar 

  19. T. Alborn, ‘The Thrift Wars: Savings Banks and Life Assurance in Victorian Britain’, paper presented to the 13th IEHA Congress, Buenos Aires, 22–26 July 2002, p. 1.

    Google Scholar 

  20. G.R. Searle, Morality and the Market in Victorian Britain (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1998).

    Book  Google Scholar 

  21. Trentmann and Daunton, ‘Worlds of Political Economy: Knowledge, Practices and Contestation’, in Worlds of Political Economy (Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan, 2005), p. 5.

    Google Scholar 

  22. M.J. Wiener, English Culture and the Decline of the Industrial Spirit 1850–1980 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1981);

    Google Scholar 

  23. D. Edgerton, Science, Technology and the British Industrial ‘Decline’ 1870–1970 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1996);

    Google Scholar 

  24. J.-P. Dormois and M. Dintenfass (eds), The British Industrial Decline (London: Routledge, 1999);

    Google Scholar 

  25. E.J. Hobsbawm, Industry and Empire (Harmondsworth: Penguin, 1999).

    Google Scholar 

  26. A. Marshall, Principles of Economics [variorum edn, 1st edn 1890], in Collected Works of Alfred Marshall, ed. by P. Groenewegen (Bristol: Overstone, 1997), vols IV–V.

    Google Scholar 

  27. J.M. Keynes, ‘Alfred Marshall 1842–1924’, Economic Journal, 34.3 (1924), pp. 311–372.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  28. Further elements can be gleaned from reading P. Groenewegen’s biography, A Soaring Eagle: Alfred Marshall 1842–1924 (Aldershot: Elgar, 1995).

    Google Scholar 

  29. KCA, JMK, EJ 6/4/30–31. This general attitude does not contrast with the religious sentiment that Marshall had rediscovered in the final years of his life, once the subtleties of theology had been put aside (ibid., EJ 6/4/34). The problems posed by evolutionism weighed heavily on the way the author experienced the relationship between faith and reason, which he tended to interpret cosmically as well as, finally, by physical relativity, that had thrown the very concept of time into crisis (ibid., EJ 6/4/31–33). After all, the Victorian epoch had been dominated by doubt, as is remarked by T.R Wright, The Religion of Humanity: The Impact of Comtean Positivism on Victorian Britain (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1986).

    Google Scholar 

  30. See C. Dickens, A Christmas Carol in Prose: Being a Ghost Story of Christmas [1843], in Christmas Books: The New Oxford Illustrated Dickens (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1954).

    Google Scholar 

  31. W.N. Parker, ‘Revolutions and Continuities in American Development’, in M. Teich and R. Porter (eds), The Industrial Revolution in National Context: Europe and the USA (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1996), p. 355.

    Google Scholar 

  32. M. Walsh, The American West: Visions and Revisions (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2005).

    Google Scholar 

  33. R.S. Cowan, A Social History of the American Technology (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1997), ch. 7.

    Google Scholar 

  34. Y. Shenhav, Manufacturing Rationality: The Engineering Foundations of the Managerial Revolution (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1999).

    Google Scholar 

  35. D.F. Noble, America by Design: Science, Technology and the Rise of Corporate Capitalism (New York: Knopf, 1977).

    Google Scholar 

  36. A.D. Chandler Jr, The Visible Hand: The Managerial Revolution in American Business (Cambridge MA: Belknap Press, 1977).

    Google Scholar 

  37. F.A. Walker, ‘Socialism’, Scribner’s Magazine, 1.1 (1887), January, p. 107.

    Google Scholar 

  38. See C.A. Barker, Henry George (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1955);

    Google Scholar 

  39. M. Gaffney, ‘Alfred Russel Wallace’s Campaign to Nationalize Land: How Darwin’s Peer Learned from John Stuart Mill and became Henry George’s Ally’, The American Journal of Economics and Sociology, 56.4 (1997), pp. 609–615 and, more generally, the journal’s special issue.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  40. S. Newcomb, ‘The Labor Question’, The North American Review, 111 (1870), July, p. 150.

    Google Scholar 

  41. See: J.B. Clark, ‘How to Deal with Communism’, New Englander and Yale Review, 37 (1878), July, pp. 533–543; Id., ‘The Nature and Progress of True Socialism’, New Englander and Yale Review, 38 (1879), July, pp. 565–582.

    Google Scholar 

  42. See: R.C. Bannister, Social Darwinism: Science and Myth in Anglo-American Social Thought (Philadelphia: Temple University Press, 1989);

    Google Scholar 

  43. C.N. Degler, In Search of Human Nature: The Decline and Revival of Darwinism in American Social Thought (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1992);

    Google Scholar 

  44. M. Hawkins, Social Darwinism in European and American Thought 1860–1945: Nature as Model and Nature as Threat (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1997), especially ch. 5.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  45. R.C. Bannister, Foreword to On Liberty, Society, and Politics: The Essential Essays of William Graham Sumner (Indianapolis: Liberty Fund, 1992), pp. ixff.

    Google Scholar 

  46. W.G. Sumner, ‘Socialism’, Scribners Monthly: An Illustrate Magazine for the People, 16.6 (1878), October, pp. 887–888.

    Google Scholar 

  47. W.G. Sumner, What Social Classes Owe to Each Other (New York: Harper, 1911 [1883]), p. 9.

    Google Scholar 

  48. W. Sombart, Warum gibt es in den Vereinigten Staaten keinen Sozialismus? (Tübingen: Mohr, 1906).

    Google Scholar 

  49. T. Veblen, The Theory of the Leisure Class, ed. by J.K. Galbraith (Boston: Houghton Mifflin, 1973 [1899]).

    Google Scholar 

  50. M. Josephson, The Robber Barons (New York: Harcourt & Brace, 1934);

    Google Scholar 

  51. D.R. Oldroyd, Darwinian Impacts (Kensington: New South Wales University Press, 1980), p. 216;

    Google Scholar 

  52. J. Rachels, Created from Animals: The Moral Implications of Darwinism (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1990), pp. 63–64.

    Google Scholar 

  53. See A. Carnegie, The Gospel of Wealth Essays and Other Writings, ed. by D. Nasaw (Harmondsworth: Penguin, 2006).

    Google Scholar 

  54. J. Jalledau, ‘The Methodological Conversion of John Bates Clark’, History of Political Economy, 7.2 (1975), pp. 209–226;

    Article  Google Scholar 

  55. K. Feder, ‘Clark: Apostle of Two-Factor Economics’, American Journal of Economics and Sociology, 62.5 (2003), p. 355;

    Article  Google Scholar 

  56. an attempt to seek some form of continuity between the two different phases can be found in J.F. Henry, ‘John Bates Clark’s Transformation’, Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 16.1 (1994), pp. 106–125.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  57. J.B. Clark, ‘Possibility of a Scientific Law of Wages’, Publications of the American Economic Association, 4.1 (1889), pp. 39–69.

    Google Scholar 

  58. J.B. Clark, ‘Distribution as Determined by a Law of Rent’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 5.3 (1891), pp. 289–318.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  59. J.B. Clark, The Distribution of Wealth: A Theory of Wages, Interest and Profits (New York: Macmillan, 1899), p. v.

    Google Scholar 

  60. T.H. Huxley, ‘Capital — The Mother of Labour: An Economical Problem Discussed from a Physiological Point of View’ [1890], in Collected Essays, vol. IX (Westport: Greenwood Press Reprints, 1968), pp. 147–187;

    Google Scholar 

  61. cf. L.B. Jones, ‘T.H. Huxley’s Critique of Henry George: An Expanded Perspective’, American Journal of Economics and Sociology, 53.2 (1994), pp. 245–255.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  62. P.H. Wicksteed, An Essay on the Co-Ordination of the Laws of Distribution (London: LSE, 1932 [1894]);

    Google Scholar 

  63. see also A.W. Flux’s review in the Economic Journal, 4 (1894), June, pp. 305–313. Ten years earlier, Wicksteed had written in the columns of Today a polemical article against Marx: ‘Das Kapital: A Criticism’ [1884], repr. in Karl Marx: Critical Responses, ed. by R. Marchionatti (London: Routledge, 1998), vol. I, pp. 218–231.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  64. L. Blanc, Organisation du travail (Paris: Inalf, 1961 [1839]).

    Google Scholar 

  65. G.B. Shaw, The Intelligent Woman’s Guide to Socialism and Capitalism (London: Constable, 1928), p. 21.

    Google Scholar 

  66. F.H. Knight, ‘The Ethics of Competition’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 37.4 (1923), p. 598.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  67. J.B. Clark, Essentials of Economic Theory (New York: Kelley, 1968 [1907]).

    Google Scholar 

  68. T. Veblen, ‘Professor Clark’s Economics’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 22.2 (1908), pp. 147–195.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  69. See G. Forges Davanzati, Ethical Codes and Income Distribution: A Study of John Bates Clark and Thorstein Veblen (London: Routledge, 2006).

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Authors

Copyright information

© 2008 Francesco Boldizzoni

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Boldizzoni, F. (2008). The Atlantic Reaction. In: Means and Ends. Palgrave Macmillan, London. https://doi.org/10.1057/9780230584143_7

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/9780230584143_7

  • Publisher Name: Palgrave Macmillan, London

  • Print ISBN: 978-1-349-36432-9

  • Online ISBN: 978-0-230-58414-3

  • eBook Packages: Palgrave History CollectionHistory (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics