Skip to main content

Capital as Money: The Emergence of Modernity

  • Chapter
Means and Ends

Abstract

In the same way that the concept of social mobility was unknown to classical antiquity so too was the concept of capital unknown, whatever one means by it (but in any case goods or money invested in order to advance personal or collective wealth). Plato, Aristotle, Cato the Censor, Cicero, Seneca and Plutarch all reviled ‘usury’ (which, like the word foenus, signified interest in a general sense). The Greeks and Romans were certainly acquainted with money, but they did not conceive of the idea of systematically making it bear fruit, and they mistrusted anyone who acquired a fortune suddenly or unexpectedly. In the town squares, forms of consumer credit were practised but the need to finance production was not felt in any way. Such activities did not involve free citizens (cives) but freedmen, and were generally stigmatized. Trade was considered a necessary evil rather than an activity to be encouraged, and the intellectuals held various attitudes ranging from disgust to resignation. By contrast, the autarchic ménage of the farm founded on slave labour was extolled above all else and, once basic needs had been provided for, otium was considered preferable to negotium.1

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

eBook
USD 16.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 119.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 119.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Notes

  1. M.I. Finley, The Ancient Economy (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1999);

    Google Scholar 

  2. P. Millett, Lending and Borrowing in Ancient Athens (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1991);

    Book  Google Scholar 

  3. S. von Reden, Exchange in Ancient Greece (London: Duckworth, 1995);

    Google Scholar 

  4. C. Perrotta, ‘Ancient Economic Thought on Wealth and Development’, European Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 10.2 (2003), pp. 177–229;

    Article  Google Scholar 

  5. M. Bianchini, La parola e la merce: una guida al pensiero economico (Reggio Emilia: Diabasis, 2004), ch. 1, passim.

    Google Scholar 

  6. Cf. J.M.H. Smith, Europe after Rome: A New Cultural History 500–1000 (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2005);

    Google Scholar 

  7. R.W. Winks and T.F. Ruiz, Medieval Europe and the World: From Late Antiquity to Modernity 500–1500 (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2005).

    Google Scholar 

  8. C.M. Cipolla, The Economic History of World Population (Harmondsworth: Penguin, 1962), p. 44;

    Google Scholar 

  9. J. Mokyr, The Lever of Riches: Technological Creativity and Economic Progress (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1990), pp. 34–35;

    Google Scholar 

  10. A.W. Crosby, The Measure of Reality: Quantification and Western Society 1250–1600 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1997), pp. 55–56.

    Google Scholar 

  11. P. Bairoch, ‘Agriculture and the Industrial Revolution 1700–1914’, in C.M. Cipolla (ed.), The Fontana Economic History of Europe, vol. III (Glasgow: Fontana/Collins, 1973), p. 469; Id., ‘La révolution industrielle et les autres grandes ruptures, ou un survol de dix mille ans d’histoire’, in Victoires et déboires: histoire économique et sociale du monde du XVIe siècle à nos jours, vol. I (Paris: Gallimard, 1997), pp. 103–104;

    Google Scholar 

  12. A.-M. Piuz, ‘Les économies traditionnelles en Europe’, in Victoires et déboires: histoire économique et sociale du monde du XVIe siècle à nos jours (Paris: Gallimard, 1997), pp. 137–138.

    Google Scholar 

  13. See D. Sweeney (ed.), Agriculture in the Middle Ages: Technology, Practice and Representation (Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press, 1995).

    Google Scholar 

  14. W. Kula, An Economic Theory of the Feudal System (London: New Left Books, 1976);

    Google Scholar 

  15. H.A. Miskimin, The Economy of Early Renaissance Europe 1300–1460 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1975), ch. 2;

    Book  Google Scholar 

  16. F. Braudel, Civilisation matérielle, économie et capitalisme, XVe–XVIIIe siècle, vol. I (Paris: Colin, 1979), Les structures du quotidien.

    Google Scholar 

  17. F. Braudel, Afterthoughts on Material Civilization and Capitalism (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1977), p. 50.

    Google Scholar 

  18. Cf. E. Coleman, ‘Cities and Communes’, in D. Abulafia (ed.), Italy in the Central Middle Ages 1000–1300 (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2004), pp. 27–57.

    Google Scholar 

  19. R. de Roover, Business, Banking and Economic Thought in Late Medieval and Early Modern Europe (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1975);

    Google Scholar 

  20. M.-T. Boyer-Xambeau, G. Deleplace and L. Gillard, Monnaie privée et pouvoir des princes: l’économie des relations monétaires à la Renaissance (Paris: CNRS-FNSP, 1986).

    Google Scholar 

  21. M. Cattini, ‘Fernand Braudel e la Storia dell’economia in Italia’, in M. Bianchini and M. Cattini (eds), Cinquecento moderno (Rome: Bulzoni, 2004), ‘Cheiron’ series, p. 210.

    Google Scholar 

  22. See F. Braudel, La Méditerranée et le monde méditerranéen à l’époque de Philippe II, 2nd edn (Paris: Colin, 1966).

    Google Scholar 

  23. K. Pribram, A History of Economic Reasoning (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1983), p. 26.

    Google Scholar 

  24. See O. Langholm, The Legacy of Scholasticism in Economic Thought: Antecedents of Choice and Power (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1998), pp. 59ff.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  25. Boyer-Xambeau, Deleplace and Gillard, Monnaie privée et pouvoir des princes; C.P. Kindleberger, Economic and Financial Crises and Transformation in Sixteenth Century Europe, ‘Essays in International Finance’ series, Department of Economics, Princeton University, no. 208, 1998, pp. 8–10; H. van der Wee, ‘Antwerp and the New Financial Methods of the 16th and 17th Centuries’, in The Low Countries in the Early Modern World (Aldershot: Variorum, 1993), pp. 145–166.

    Google Scholar 

  26. Cf. Oxford Latin Dictionary, ed. by P.G.W. Glare (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1996), s.v. capitalis.

    Google Scholar 

  27. Cf. C. Ducange, Glossarium mediae et inflmae latinitatis (Niort: Favre, 1883 [1678]), s.v. capitale.

    Google Scholar 

  28. Quoted in Grande dizionario della lingua italiana, ed. by S. Battaglia (Turin: UTET, 1961–2004), s.v. capitale.

    Google Scholar 

  29. Quoted in Oxford English Dictionary, ed. by J.A.H. Murray et al. (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1961), s.v. capital.

    Google Scholar 

  30. Ibid. There are records of earlier uses of the word, apparently limited to the lexis of accounting. ‘Capitall’ appears in bookkeeping manuals written by James Peele (1569) and John Mellis (1588), who imported the double-entry method from Italy into England (R.D. Richards, ‘Early History of the Term Capital’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 40.2 (1926), p. 330).

    Article  Google Scholar 

  31. Grande dizionario della lingua italiana, s.v. capitale. This seems to be the main meaning for E. Cannan, ‘Early History of the Term Capital’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 35.3 (1921), pp. 469–470.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  32. See F. Boldizzoni, ‘The Italian Way to Seignorage: Public Finance, Personal Power and Inflation Shocks in the Po Valley between the 16th and 17th Centuries’, The Journal of European Economic History, 33.3 (2004), p. 630, footnote 18.

    Google Scholar 

  33. Cf. R. de Roover, ‘What is Dry Exchange? A Contribution to the Study of English Mercantilism’, Journal of Political Economy, 52.3 (1944), pp. 250–266.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  34. Bianchini, La parola e la merce, p. 194. Cf. F. Boldizzoni, ‘Davanzati e Hobbes: nascita e diffusione di un paradigma (XVI–XVIII secolo)’, Il pensiero economico italiano, 13.1 (2005), p. 11.

    Google Scholar 

  35. See C.M. Cipolla, Le avventure della lira (Bologna: Il Mulino, 2001).

    Google Scholar 

  36. B. Mandeville, The Fable of the Bees: Or, Private Vices, Publick Benefits (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1924 [1714]).

    Google Scholar 

  37. N. Machiavelli, Il Principe (Milan: Rizzoli, 2006 [1532, written 1513]);

    Google Scholar 

  38. see Q. Skinner, Machiavelli (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2001), ch. 2.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  39. The text is given in M. Grice Hutchinson, The School of Salamanca: Readings in Spanish Monetary Theory, 1544–1605 (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1952), App. I. The passage quoted is on p. 125.

    Google Scholar 

  40. T. de Vio (Caietanus), De cambiis [1499], in Scripta philosophica: opuscula oeconomico-socialia, ed. by P. Zammit (Rome: Institutum Angelicum, 1934).

    Google Scholar 

  41. M. Grice Hutchinson, Early Economic Thought in Spain 1177–1740 (London: Allen & Unwin, 1978), p. 90.

    Google Scholar 

  42. See M. Tavuzzi, Prierias: The Life and Works of Silvestro Mazzolini da Prierio 1456–1527 (Durham NC: Duke University Press, 1997).

    Google Scholar 

  43. L. Baeck, The Mediterranean Tradition in Economic Thought (London: Routledge, 1994), pp. 188–189.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  44. J.A. Schumpeter, History of Economic Analysis (New York: Oxford University Press, 1954), p. 104, footnote 31.

    Google Scholar 

  45. Grice Hutchinson, Early Economic Thought in Spain, pp. 52–54; M. Cattini, I contadini di San Felice: metamorfosi di un mondo rurale nell’Emilia dell’Età moderna (Turin: Einaudi, 1984), pp. 122ff.

    Google Scholar 

  46. K. Polanyi, C.M. Arensberg and H.W. Pearson (eds), Trade and Market in the Early Empires: Economies in History and Theory (Glencoe: The Free Press, 1957), pp. 250ff.

    Google Scholar 

  47. A. Genovesi, Lezioni di economia civile [1765], in Scrittori classici italiani di economia politica. Parte moderna, ed. by P. Custodi, vol. IX (Milan: Destefanis, 1803),9 p. 177. The need to distinguish between categories of borrowers was part of public ethics even above religious principles: Francis Bacon himself in 1625, suggested that two rates of maximum interest should be introduced into England: one for ordinary loans and another, higher one, for business loans. See M. Grice Hutchinson, Economic Thought in Spain: Selected Essays, ed. by L.S. Moss and C.K. Ryan (Aldershot: Elgar, 1993), p. 18.

    Google Scholar 

  48. B.W. Dempsey, Interest and Usury (Washington DC: American Council on Public Affairs, 1943).

    Google Scholar 

  49. F. Boldizzoni, ‘Il governo della moneta a Milano dal 1650 alla Guerra di successione spagnola’, Storia economica, 6.3 (2003), p. 420, footnote 119.

    Google Scholar 

  50. M. Rothbard, Economic Thought before Adam Smith: An Austrian Perspective on the History of Economic Thought (Aldershot: Elgar, 1995), p. 114.

    Google Scholar 

  51. Rothbard, Economic Thought before Adam Smith, p. 125. As for the fact that this was not previously the norm (and in many parts of Europe continued not to be) cf. C. Muldrew, The Economy of Obligation: The Culture of Credit and Social Relations in Early Modern England (Basingstoke: Macmillan, 1998).

    Google Scholar 

  52. See D. Sella, Italy in the Seventeenth Century (London: Longman, 1997).

    Google Scholar 

  53. M. Bianchini, ‘La riflessione economica nell’Italia seicentesca’, in M. Cattini (ed.), Il Seicento: un secolo in chiaroscuro (Brescia: Astrea, 1984), ‘Cheiron’ series, p. 36.

    Google Scholar 

  54. B. Pascal, Les Provinciales: ou les Lettres écrites parLouis deMontalte à un provincial de ses amis et aux RR. PP. Jésuites, ed. by L. Cognet and G. Ferreyrolles (Paris: Bordas, 1992), VIIIe lettre, 28 mai 1656.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Authors

Copyright information

© 2008 Francesco Boldizzoni

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Boldizzoni, F. (2008). Capital as Money: The Emergence of Modernity. In: Means and Ends. Palgrave Macmillan, London. https://doi.org/10.1057/9780230584143_2

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/9780230584143_2

  • Publisher Name: Palgrave Macmillan, London

  • Print ISBN: 978-1-349-36432-9

  • Online ISBN: 978-0-230-58414-3

  • eBook Packages: Palgrave History CollectionHistory (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics