Paul Samuelson pp 193-227 | Cite as
Samuelson’s Approach to Revealed Preference Theory: Some Recent Advances
- 237 Downloads
Abstract
Since Paul Samuelson introduced the theory of revealed preference, it has become one of the most important concepts in economics. This chapter surveys some recent contributions in the revealed preference literature. We depart from Afriat’s theorem, which provides the conditions for a data set to be consistent with the utility maximization hypothesis. We provide and motivate a new condition, which we call the Varian inequalities. The advantage of the Varian inequalities is that they can be formulated as a set of mixed integer linear inequalities, which are linear in the quantity and price data. We show how the Varian inequalities can be used to derive revealed preference tests for weak separability and show how they can be used to formulate tests of the collective household model. Finally, we discuss measurement errors in the observed data and measures of goodness-of-fit, power, and predictive success.
Keywords
Afriat’s theorem collective household model GARP mixed integer linear programming revealed preference Varian inequalities weak separabilityNotes
Acknowledgements
Thomas Demuynck acknowledges financial support by the Fonds de la Recherche Scientifique-FNRS under grant nr F.4516.18. Per Hjertstrand acknowledges financial support from Jan Wallander och Tom Hedelius stiftelse, Marcus och Marianne Wallenbergs stiftelse and Johan och Jakob Söderbergs stiftelse.
References
- Adams, A., L. Cherchye, B. De Rock and E. Verriest (2014) “Now or Later? Time Inconsistency, Collective Choice and Revealed Preference,” American Economic Review, 104: 4147–4183.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Afriat, S.N. (1967) “The Construction of Utility Functions from Expenditure Data,” International Economic Review, 8: 67–77.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Afriat, S.N. (1969) “The Construction of Separable Utility Functions from Expenditure Data,” Tech. rep., University of North Carolina.Google Scholar
- Afriat, S.N. (1972) “Efficiency Estimation of Production Functions,” International Economic Review, 13: 568–598.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Andreoni, J., B.J. Gillen and W.T Harbaugh (2013) “The Power of Revealed Preference Tests: Ex-Post Evaluation of Experimental Design,” Tech. rep., University of California, San Diego.Google Scholar
- Apps, P.F. and R. Rees (1988) “Taxation and the Household,” Journal of Public Economics, 35: 355–369.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Beatty, T.K.M. and I. Crawford (2011) “How Demanding Is the Revealed Preference Approach to Demand,” American Economic Review, 101: 2782–2795.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Becker, G.S. (1962) “Irrational Behavior and Economic Theory,” Journal of Political Economy, 70: 1–13.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Belongia, M.T. and K.A. Chrystal (1991) “An Admissible Monetary Aggregate for the United Kingdom,” Review of Economics and Statistics, 73: 497–503.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Bergstrom, T.C., L. Blume and H.R. Varian (1986) “On the Private Provision of Public Goods,” Journal of Public Economics, 29: 25–49.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Blundell, R., M. Browning and I. Crawford (2003) “Nonparametric Engel Curves and Revealed Preference,” Econometrica, 71: 205–240.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Blundell, R., M. Browning and I. Crawford (2008) “Best Nonparametric Bounds on Demand Responses,” Econometrica, 76: 1227–1262.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Bronars, S.G. (1987) “The Power of Nonparametric Tests of Preference Maximization,” Econometrica, 55: 693–698.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Brown, D.J. and C. Calsamiglia (2007) “The Nonparametric Approach to Applied Welfare Analysis,” Economic Theory, 31: 183–188.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Brown, D.J. and R. Kannan (2008) “Two Algorithms for Solving the Walrasian Equilibrium Inequalities,” in D. Brown and F. Kubler (eds.) Computational Aspects of General Equilibrium Theory: Refutable Theories of Value. Lecture Notes in Economics and Mathematical Systems. Berlin, Springer.Google Scholar
- Brown, D.J. and R.L. Matzkin (1996) “Testable Restrictions on the Equilibrium Manifold,” Econometrica, 64: 1249–1262.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Brown, D.J. and C. Shannon (2000) “Uniqueness, Stability, and Comparative Statics in Rationalizable Walrasian Markets,” Econometrica, 68: 1529–1540.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Browning, M. (1989) “A Nonparametric Test of the Life-Cycle Rational Expectations Hypothesis,” International Economic Review, 30: 979–992.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Carvajal, A. and N. Gonzáles (2014) “On Refutability of the Nash Bargaining Solution,” Journal of Mathematical Economics, 50: 177–186.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Carvajal, A. and X. Song (2018) “Testing Pareto Efficiency and Competitive Equilibrium in Economies with Public Goods,” Journal of Mathematical Economics, 75: 19–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Chambers, C.P. and F. Echenique (2014) “On the Consistency of Data with Bargaining Theories,” Theoretical Economics, 9: 137–162.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Chambers, C.P. and F. Echenique (2016) Revealed Preference Theory. Cambridge, UK, Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Chambers, C.P., F. Echenique and E. Shmaya (2010) “On Behavioural Complementarities and Its Implications,” Journal of Economic Theory, 145: 2332–2355.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Chambers, C.P., F. Echenique and E. Shmaya (2011) “Testable Implications of Gross Substitutes in Demand for Two Goods,” American Economic Journal: Microeconomics, 3: 129–136.Google Scholar
- Cherchye, L., B. De Rock and F. Vermeulen (2007) “The Collective Model of Household Consumption: A Nonparametric Characterization,” Econometrica, 75: 553–574.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Cherchye, L., I. Crawford, B. De Rock and F. Vermeulen (2009a) “The Revealed Preference Approach to Demand,” in D. Slottje (ed.) Quantifying Consumer Preferences: Estimating Demand Systems. Contributions to Economic Analysis. Bingley, UK, Emerald Press.Google Scholar
- Cherchye, L., B. De Rock and F. Vermeulen (2009b) “Opening the Black Box of Intra-Household Decision-Making: Theory and Nonparametric Empirical Tests of General Collective Consumption Models,” Journal of Political Economy, 117: 1074–1104.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Cherchye, L., B. De Rock and F. Vermeulen (2011a) “The Revealed Preference Approach to Collective Consumption Behavior: Testing and Sharing Rule Recovery,” Review of Economic Studies, 78: 176–198.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Cherchye, L., T. Demuynck and B. De Rock (2011b) “Revealed Preference Analysis of Noncooperative Household Consumption,” Economic Journal, 121: 1073–1096.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Cherchye, L., T. Demuynck and B. De Rock (2011c) “Testable Implications of General Equilibrium Models: An Integer Programming Approach,” Journal of Mathematical Economics, 47: 564–575.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Cherchye, L., T. Demuynck and B. De Rock (2013) “Nash Bargained Consumption Decisions: A Revealed Preference Analysis,” Economic Journal, 123: 195–235.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Cherchye, L., T. Demuynck and B. De Rock (2014) “Revealed Preference Analysis for Convex Rationalization on Nonlinear Budget Sets,” Journal of Economic Theory, 152: 224–236.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Cherchye, L., T. Demuynck, B. De Rock and P. Hjertstrand (2015a) “Revealed Preference Tests for Weak Separability: An Integer Programming Approach,” Journal of Econometrics, 186: 129–141.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Cherchye, L., T. Demuynck and B. De Rock (2015b) “Is Utility Transferable? A Revealed Preference Analysis,” Theoretical Economics, 10: 51–65.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Cherchye, L., B. De Rock, T. Demuynck and F. Vermeulen (2017) “Household Consumption When the Marriage Is Stable,” American Economic Review, 107: 1507–1534.Google Scholar
- Cherchye, L., T. Demuynck and B. De Rock (2018) “Normality of Demand in a Two-goods Setting,” Journal of Economic Theory, 173: 361–382.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Chiappori, P.-A. (1988) “Rational Household Labor Supply,” Econometrica, 56: 63–89.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Chiappori, P.-A. (1992) “Collective Labor Supply and Welfare,” Journal of Political Economy, 100: 437–467.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Chiappori, P.-A. and J.-C. Rochet (1987) “Revealed Preferences and Differentiable Demand,” Econometrica, 55: 687–691.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Cosaert, S. and T. Demuynck (2015) “Revealed Preference Theory for Finite Choice Sets,” Economic Theory, 59: 169–200.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Cosaert, S. and T. Demuynck (2018) “Nonparametric Welfare and Demand Analysis with Unobserved Individual Heterogeneity,” Review of Economic and Statistics, 100: 349–361.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Crawford, I. (2010) “Habits Revealed,” Review of Economic Studies, 77: 1382–1402.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Crawford, I. and B. De Rock (2014) “Empirical Revealed Preference,” Annual Review of Economics, 6: 503–524.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Dean, M. and D. Martin (2016) “Measuring Rationality with the Minimum Cost of Revealed Preference Violations,” Review of Economics and Statistics, 98: 524–534.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Demuynck, T. (2015) “Statistical Inference for Measures of Predictive Success,” Theory and Decision, 79: 689–699.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Demuynck, T. and C. Seel (2018) “Revealed Preference with Limited Consideration,” American Economic Journal: Microeconomics, 10: 102–131.Google Scholar
- Demuynck, T. and E. Verriest (2013) “I’ll Never Forget My First Cigarette: A Revealed Preference Analysis of the Habits as Durables Model,” International Economic Review, 54: 717–738.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Diewert, W.E. (1973) “Afriat and Revealed Preference Theory,” Review of Economic Studies, 40: 419–425.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Diewert, W.E. (2012) “Afriat’s Theorem and Some Extensions to Choice Under Uncertainty,” Economic Journal, 122: 305–331.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Diewert, W.E. and C. Parkan (1985) “Tests for the Consistency of Consumer Data,” Journal of Econometrics, 30: 127–147.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Echenique, F. (2014) “Testing for Separability Is Hard,” Tech. rep., Caltech.Google Scholar
- Echenique, F., S. Lee and M. Shum (2011) “The Money Pump as a Measure of Revealed Preference Violations,” Journal of Political Economy, 119: 1201–1223.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Echenique, F. and K. Saito (2015) “Savage in the Market,” Econometrica, 83: 1467–1495.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Elger, C.T., B.E. Jones, D.L. Edgerton and J.M. Binner (2008) “A Note on the Optimal Level of Monetary Aggregation in the United Kingdom,” Macroeconomic Dynamics, 12: 117–131.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Fisher, D. and A.R. Fleissig (1997) “Monetary Aggregation and the Demand for Assets,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 29: 458–475.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Fleissig, A.R. and G.A. Whitney (2003) “A New PC-Based Test for Varian’s Weak Separability Condition,” Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, 21: 133–145.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Fleissig, A.R. and G.A. Whitney (2005) “Testing for the Significance of Violations of Afriat’s Inequalities,” Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, 23: 355–362.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Forges, F. and V. Iehlé (2013) “Essential Data, Budget Sets and Rationalization,” Economic Theory, 54: 449–461.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Forges, F. and V. Iehlé (2014) “Afriat’s Theorem for Indivisible Goods,” Journal of Mathematical Economics, 54: 1–6.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Forges, F. and E. Minelli (2009) “Afriat’s Theorem for General Budget Sets,” Journal of Economic Theory, 144: 135–145.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Ginsberg, W. (1973) “Concavity and Quasiconcavity in Economics,” Journal of Economic Theory, 6: 596–605.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Green, E.J. and K. Osband (1991) “A Revealed Preference Theory for Expected Utility,” Review of Economic Studies, 58: 677–695.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Gross, J. and D. Kaiser (1996) “Two Simple Algorithms for Generating a Subset of Data Consistent with WARP and Other Binary Relations,” Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, 14: 251–255.Google Scholar
- Heufer, J. (2014) “Nonparametric Comparative Revealed Risk Aversion,” Journal of Economic Theory, 153: 569–616.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Heufer, J. and P. Hjertstrand (2015) “Consistent Subsets: Computationally Feasible Methods to Compute the Houtman-Maks-Index,” Economics Letters, 128: 87–89.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Heufer, J. and P. Hjertstrand (2019) “Homothetic Efficiency: Theory and Applications," forthcoming in Journal of Business and Economic Statistics.Google Scholar
- Hjertstrand, P. (2009) “A Monte Carlo Study of the Necessary and Sufficient Conditions for Weak Separability," Advances in Econometrics, 24: 151–182.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Hjertstrand, P. (2013) “A Simple Method to Account for Measurement Errors in Revealed Preference Tests," IFN Working Paper 990, Research Institute of Industrial Economics, Stockholm.Google Scholar
- Hjertstrand, P. and J.L. Swofford (2012) “Revealed Preference Tests for Consistency with Weakly Separable Indirect Utility,” Theory and Decision, 72: 245–256.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Hjertstrand, P. and J.L. Swofford (2019) “Revealed Preference Tests of Indirect and Homothetic Weak Separability of Financial Assets, Consumption and Leisure," forthcoming in Journal of Financial Stability.Google Scholar
- Hjertstrand, P., J.L. Swofford and G.A. Whitney (2016) “Mixed Integer Programming Revealed Preference Tests of Utility Maximization and Weak Separability of Consumption, Leisure and Money,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 48: 1547–1561.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Hjertstrand, P., J.L. Swofford and G.A. Whitney (2019) “Index Numbers and Revealed Preference Rankings,” forthcoming in Macroeconomic Dynamics.Google Scholar
- Hoderlein, S. and J. Stoye (2014) “Revealed Preference in a Heterogeneous Population,” Review of Economics and Statistics, 96: 197–213.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Houthakker, H.S. (1950) “Revealed Preference and the Utility Function,” Economica, 17: 159–174.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Houtman, M. and J.A.H. Maks (1985) “Determining All Maximal Data Subsets Consistent with Revealed Preference,” Kwantitatieve Methoden, 89: 89–104.Google Scholar
- Jones, B.E., D. Dutkowsky and C.T. Elger (2005) “Sweep Programs and Optimal Money Aggregation,” Journal of Banking and Finance, 29: 483–508.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Jones, B.E. and D.L. Edgerton (2009) “Testing Utility Maximization with Measurement Errors in the Data,” Advances in Econometrics, 24: 199–236.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Kawaguchi, K. (2017) “Testing Rationality Without Restricting Heterogeneity,” Journal of Econometrics, 197: 153–171.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Kitamura, Y. and J. Stoye (2018) “Nonparametric Analysis of Random Utility Models,” Econometrica, 86: 1883–1909.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Matzkin, R.L. (1991) “Axioms of Revealed Preference for Nonlinear Choice Sets,” Econometrica, 59: 1779–1786.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Matzkin, R.L. and M.K. Richter (1991) “Testing Strictly Concave Rationality,” Journal of Economic Theory, 53: 287–303.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- McFadden, D.L. and M.K. Richter (1971) “On the Extension of a Set Function on a Set of Events to a Probability on the Generated Boolean \(\sigma \)-Algebra,” Tech. rep., University of California, Berkeley.Google Scholar
- McFadden, D.L. (2005) “Revealed Stochastic Preference: A Synthesis,” Economic Theory, 26: 245–264.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Nishimura, H., E.A. Ok and J.K.H. Quah (2017) “A Comprehensive Approach to Revealed Preference Theory,” American Economic Review, 107: 1239–1263.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Polisson, M. and J.K.H. Quah (2013) “Revealed Preference in a Discrete Consumption Space,” American Economic Journal: Microeconomics, 5: 28–34.Google Scholar
- Polisson, M., J.K.H. Quah and L. Renou (2017) “Revealed Preferences Over Risk and Uncertainty,” School of Economics and Finance Discussion Paper 1706, University of St Andrews.Google Scholar
- Samuelson, P.A. (1938) “A Note on the Pure Theory of Consumer’s Behavior,” Economica, 5: 61–71.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Samuelson, P.A. (1948) “Consumption Theory in Terms of Revealed Preference,” Economica, 15: 243–253.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Selten, R. (1991) “Properties of a Measure of Predictive Success,” Mathematical Social Sciences, 21: 153–167.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Smeulders, B., L. Cherchye, B. De Rock and F.C.R. Spieksma (2013) “The Money Pump as a Measure of Revealed Preference Violations: A Comment,” Journal of Political Economy, 121: 1248–1258.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Swofford, J.L. and G.A. Whitney (1987) “Nonparametric Tests of Utility Maximization and Weak Separability for Consumption, Leisure and Money,” Review of Economics and Statistics, 69: 458–464.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Swofford, J.L. and G.A. Whitney (1994) “A Revealed Preference Test for Weakly Separable Utility Maximization with Incomplete Adjustment,” Journal of Econometrics, 60: 235–249.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- van Bruggen, P. and J. Heufer (2017) “Afriat in the Lab,” Journal of Economic Theory, 169: 546–550.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Varian, H.R. (1982) “The Nonparametric Approach to Demand Analysis,” Econometrica, 50: 945–974.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Varian, H.R. (1983a) “Non-Parametric Tests of Consumer Behavior,” Review of Economic Studies, 50: 99–110.Google Scholar
- Varian, H.R. (1983b) “Nonparametric Tests of Models of Investor Behavior,” Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 18: 269–278.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Varian, H.R. (1984) “The Nonparametric Approach to Production Analysis,” Econometrica, 52: 579–597.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Varian, H.R. (1985) “Non-Parametric Analysis of Optimizing Behaviour with Measurement Error,” Journal of Econometrics, 30: 445–458.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Varian, H.R. (1988) “Estimating Risk Aversion from Arrow-Debreu Portfolio Choice,” Econometrica, 56: 973–979.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Varian, H.R. (1990) “Goodness-of-Fit in Optimizing Models,” Journal of Econometrics, 46: 125–140.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Varian, H.R. (2006) “Revealed Preference,” in M. Szenberg, L. Ramrattan and A.A Gottesman (eds.) Samuelson Economics and the Twenty-First Century. Oxford, Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
- Warshall, S. (1962) “A Theorem of Boolean Matrices,” Journal of the American Association of Computing Machinery, 9: 11–12.CrossRefGoogle Scholar