Skip to main content

Administrative Capacity and Control

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
National Administrations in EU Trade Policy

Part of the book series: European Administrative Governance ((EAGOV))

  • 254 Accesses

Abstract

Does a member state’s administrative capacity explain varying level of control? In addition to studying the relationship between the frequency of signalling and a member state’s administrative capacity, this chapter also ascertains the explanatory power of administrative capacity in understanding the signalling strategies applied (bilateral or collective) as well as the stage in the negotiation at which such signalling occurs. Following a brief recapitulation of the main dependent and independent variable, this chapter introduces and tests three hypotheses through a series of bootstrapped regression models. The results provide support that administrative capacity is an important factor in explaining member-state behaviour in the Council.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

eBook
USD 16.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    The assumption that the speed of formulating a policy position is also translated into being relatively more active in the “proactive” than the “reactive” stages of the negotiation can be subject for debate. I do not see any reason why a member state would delay the signalling of a position once it has been formulated.

  2. 2.

    This notwithstanding, post estimation of the models revealed that the null hypothesis of normally distributed error could not be rejected. Neither could we reject the hypothesis of homoscedastic errors.

  3. 3.

    An alternative formulation of the model was also estimated using only monitoring capacity and CMB as independent variables. Regardless of the choice of dependent and independent variables, the CMB had no significant effect (while monitoring still had).

  4. 4.

    Originally, a proper network analysis was aspired through a web survey throughout the national administrations. The level of detail in the data ultimately gathered differs significantly from the original aspirations, for both the involvement of other public actors and the intensity of the coordination system.

  5. 5.

    The survey included the following question to measure the “demand for control”: “How often do you feel that the Commission’s initial proposals deviate from your country’s preferences?”

References

  • Alesina, A. & Spolaore, E. (1997). On the number and size of nations. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112(4), 1027–1056.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, A. & Spolaore, E. (2003). The size of nations. Cambridge (Mass.): MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Haverland, M. & Liefferink, D. (2012a). Member State interest articulation in the Commission phase. Institutional pre-conditions for influencing “Brussels.”. Journal of European Public Policy, 19(2), 179–197.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haverland, M. & Liefferink, D. (2012b). Member State interest articulation in the Commission phase. Institutional pre-conditions for influencing “Brussels.”. Journal of European Public Policy, 19(2), 179–197.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • King, G., Keohane, R. O., & Verba, S. (1994). Designing social inquiry: Scientific inference in qualitative research. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Meier, K. J. & O’toole, L. J. (2013). Subjective Organizational Performance and Measurement Error: Common source bias and spurious relationships. Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory, 23(2), 429–456.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Napel, S., Widgrén, M., & Mayer, A. (2013). Strategic a priori power in the European Union’s Codecision Procedure Recalculated for EU28. In M. Holler & H. Nurmi (Eds.), Power, voting and voting power: 30 years after (pp. 553–571). Berlin: Springer.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Naurin, D. (2007). Network Capital and Cooperation Patterns in the Working Groups of the Council of the EU. EUI Working Paper RSCAS, 14, 36.

    Google Scholar 

  • Panke, D. (2010a). Good instructions in no time? Domestic Coordination of EU Policies in 19 Small States. West European Politics, 33(4), 770–790.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Panke, D. (2010b). Small states in the European Union: Structural disadvantages in EU policy-making and counter-strategies. Journal of European Public Policy, 17(6), 799–817.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Podsakoff, P. M., MacKenzie, S. B., Lee, J.-Y., & Podsakoff, N. P. (2003). Common method biases in behavioral research: A critical review of the literature and recommended remedies. The Journal of Applied Psychology, 88(5), 879–903.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tallberg, J. (2008). Bargaining power in the European Council*. Journal of Common Market Studies, 46(3), 685–708.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Copyright information

© 2016 The Editor(s) (if applicable) and The Author(s)

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Adriaensen, J. (2016). Administrative Capacity and Control. In: National Administrations in EU Trade Policy. European Administrative Governance. Palgrave Macmillan, London. https://doi.org/10.1057/978-1-137-54767-5_7

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics