Skip to main content

The Rise and Decline of Modern Trade Union Insurance, 1900–65

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Book cover Mutual Insurance 1550-2015

Part of the book series: Palgrave Studies in the History of Finance ((PSHF))

  • 645 Accesses

Abstract

Between the fin de siècle and the zenith of the welfare state lay not only two world wars and a Great Depression, but also the rise and decline of micro-insurance provided by modern trade unions. Unions kept alive working models of large-scale micro-insurance and, indeed, developed the only viable such model in the case of unemployment. They did so in a country undergoing economic, religious, political, and social transformation. We will discuss the scope of coverage, and terms and conditions, including those relating to classic insurance issues. We discuss the place of micro-insurance among unionists and the population at large, its place in the political climate of de-pillarization, economic growth, and the egalitarian revolution, and its role in the mixed economy of welfare, where state insurance seemed destined to dominate forever.

A version of this chapter has been published in the Economic History Review, where it benefited greatly from comments by George Boyer, Joost van Genabeek, Chris Gordon, Michael Hechter, Lex Heerma van Voss, Ivo Kuypers, Marcel van der Linden, Erik Nijhof, Carine van Oosteren, Arthur van Riel, Peter Schrage, Marlou Schrover, Henk van der Velden, Hanke van Vonderen, and the anonymous referees of the EcHR. Pascal Kreijen and Hanke van Vonderen kindly assisted in collecting data. I am most grateful to all.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 89.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD 119.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    De Jonge (1968) and van Zanden and van Riel (2000).

  2. 2.

    Van Leeuwen (1998a, pp. 288–90), van Zanden and van Riel (2000, pp. 316–23), and de Rooy (2002, passim).

  3. 3.

    The following is based on Schwitters (1991, pp. 4, 47–51, 78, 100, 209–10, 230–5).

  4. 4.

    By then, it was compulsory to have at least four years’ secondary education, a period extended in 1975 to the year in which the child became 17. Tertiary education was not compulsory, but an ever-increasing proportion of the Dutch population, young men and women, did take advantage of it, especially after 1945. See Jensma and de Vries (1997) and Mandemakers (1999).

  5. 5.

    Centraal Bureau voor de Statistiek (2014).

  6. 6.

    Or, as Wintle has termed it, ‘confessionally dominated pluralism’. Lijphart (1968), de Rooy (1983, pp. 174–80), Post (1989), and Wintle (2000, p. 258).

  7. 7.

    De Rooy (1983, pp. 155, 139).

  8. 8.

    Ibid., pp. 208–12, 221, 225.

  9. 9.

    The development of Dutch unions is covered by Harmsen and Reinalda (1975) and by Harmsen et al. (1980). Summary descriptions in English are provided by Windmuller (1969, Chap. 1) and van den Berg (1995, Chap. 3).

  10. 10.

    It is generally held that the CBS data are reliable. The data may, nevertheless, suffer from a mild form of under-registration as unions did not always send the CBS all the data requested, either because of mistrust and a penchant for secrecy or simply because they forgot. A further potential source of under-registration is the fact that some unions may have supplied incomplete information to the CBS in the form of data that failed to meet the requirements of the material on which Table 4.1 is based. If so, the aggregated totals in Table 4.1 should differ significantly from the simple totals provided by the CBS. To test this, the numbers of union members in Table 4.1 have been compared with the totals in Harmsen and Reinalda (1975, pp. 426–9), which are based on simple CBS totals. On average, data in Table 4.1 were 3% lower, which could be due in part to small differences in the date to which the data refer, although both sets of data should in theory relate to 1 January. The difference is greatest in 1921, when it amounts to 11%. In addition, the number of unionists insured against unemployment in Table 4.1 has been compared with the totals tabulated in the CBS, Jaarcijfers for the years 1921–40. The data in Table 4.1 are 1% lower than the simple CBS totals. The difference is greatest (7%) in 1921, which could be due to under-registration but also to differences in the date to which the data relate, especially because membership at that time fluctuated markedly. So, generally, save perhaps for 1921, the tabulated data do not appear to show evidence of gross under-registration.

  11. 11.

    Several definitions of the labour force can be employed. Comparative trade union research often makes use of the data published by Visser (1989). These data have been used here as well. While Fig. 4.2 shows the ensuing percentages of insured unionists in the labour force thus defined, the underlying data in Table 4.1 will allow the reader to construct figures based on an alternative definition of the labour force.

  12. 12.

    A limited cross-validation is possible by comparing data on socialist unemployment schemes in 1915 with those for all unions in Table 4.5 as reported by the Staatscommissie (1914, vol. ix, pp. 1147–245). The average eligibility requirement was 55 weeks (Table 4.2) compared with 53 weeks (national survey), the average period of coverage 54 days and 57 days respectively, and the average weekly allowance five guilders in both sources. A further cross-validation is possible by comparing the average level of unemployment benefit offered by socialist and Protestant unions, given in Tables 4.2 and 4.3, with a published national series. This series relates to all unionists, rather than just socialists or Protestants, and was estimated using sources and methods different from those used here. It gives only one average as opposed to one for married and one for unmarried union members; nor does it include agricultural workers, whose allowances were lower on average than those of non-agricultural workers. The national series suggests levels of unemployment benefit averaged 5 guilders (1915), 14 guilders (1920), 12 guilders (1925), 13 guilders (1930), and 13 guilders (1934). See Schrage et al. (1989, p. 393). These figures correspond closely with the data in Tables 4.2 and 4.3: all show the same pattern of change, and their respective levels are similar. The sources for Tables 4.2 and 4.3 do not give information on years after 1934.

  13. 13.

    Van der Veen and van Zanden (1984, p. 223).

  14. 14.

    In 1910–11, average weekly income was 17 guilders, of which 14 guilders was earned by men. In 1918, average weekly income was 26 guilders, of which 21 guilders was earned by men. No such data are available for 1920, but an estimate can be obtained by using the figures for 1918 and inflating them according to an index of nominal wages. See ibid., p. 228. The result suggests average weekly incomes in 1920 of 31 guilders, of which 21 guilders was earned by men.

  15. 15.

    Cf. Emery and Emery (1999, Chap. 4, esp. pp. 64–85). On p. 5 they note that for the United States ‘friendly society insurance provisions were more efficient than those of commercial insurers’.

  16. 16.

    Goedhart (1926, pp. 54–5).

  17. 17.

    De Rooy (1979, pp. 87–91, 164–70, 203–4), Cillekens and Roebroeks (1983, pp. 42–5), Nijhof et al. (1983, pp. 40–3, 83–9), and Groot (1987, p. 254).

  18. 18.

    Recter (1940, pp. 109–13), de Rooy (1979, pp. 166–7), and Nijhof et al. (1983, pp. 42–3).

  19. 19.

    Goedhart (1926, p. 62); see also Recter (1940, p. 113).

  20. 20.

    Staatscommissie (1914, vol. ix, p. 867). The quote is from the minority report, but the majority thought likewise. See pp. 806–16.

  21. 21.

    Ibid., vol. ix, pp. 731, 757–8. See also Goedhart (1926, p. 16) and Morren (1941, p. 3). The foreign insurers were La mutuelle Parisienne, La mutuelle du foyer, Die Norddeutsche Versicherung- und Rentenbank in Hamburg, and Der Zentralverein für Versicherung gegen Unverschuldete Arbeitslosigkeit in Stuttgart.

  22. 22.

    Webb and Webb (1897, p. 156) and Hanson (1975, pp. 255–6).

  23. 23.

    Hechter and Kanazawa (1993, esp. pp. 460–1, 480).

  24. 24.

    This was not invariably the case, as is illustrated by the example to be discussed later, which relates to workers in the city of Maastricht choosing between a Catholic and a socialist union based on the level of union benefits.

  25. 25.

    Soeteman (1962, p. 137).

  26. 26.

    General histories can be found in Staatscommissie (1914, vol. ix, pp. 749–806), Goedhart (1926), Berger (1936), Morren (1941), de Rooy (1979), and Schrage and Nijhof (1992).

  27. 27.

    Morren (1941, p. 77).

  28. 28.

    Ibid., pp. 96–7, 134–5.

  29. 29.

    Goedhart (1926, p. 90).

  30. 30.

    Mannoury (1985, p. 193). See also de Rooy (1979, p. 25) and Nijhof and Schrage (1984, p. 274).

  31. 31.

    Oudegeest (1914, p. 37).

  32. 32.

    As advocated, for example, by van Tijn (1976).

  33. 33.

    Olson (1965, pp. 132–48). See also Crouch (1982, pp. 43–74) and Freeman and Medoff (1984, pp. 61–77).

  34. 34.

    Olson (1965, p. 91).

  35. 35.

    The studies by Ashenfelter and Pencavel (1969) and Bain and Elsheikh (1976) have been influential. See esp. pp. 2–57 of the latter for a review of the literature. For more recent reviews see, for example, Western (1993, 1995) and van den Berg (1995, Chaps. 2 and 6).

  36. 36.

    Examples of union strength are strikes and shop-floor visibility, while cost-benefit considerations include the extent of union/non-union wage differentials and fringe benefits.

  37. 37.

    Bymholt (1894, vol. 2, pp. 403, 405).

  38. 38.

    Cillekens and Roebroeks (1983, pp. 65, 83, 114–5).

  39. 39.

    Van de Vall (1963, p. 153).

  40. 40.

    Nijhof and Schrage (1984, pp. 270–7); see also Nijhof et al. (1983, p. 55). It is perhaps interesting to note that during the Great Depression even unions with relatively low expected benefits experienced a modest increase in membership.

  41. 41.

    Van de Vall (1963, pp. 147–8).

  42. 42.

    It should be noted, however, that the survey was conducted during a period when unionists were dissatisfied with what they perceived to be the complacent attitude of the union with regard to wage increases. See van den Berg (1995, p. 65).

  43. 43.

    Ibid., p. 60. See also Visser (1989, pp. 150–1). If part-time workers are excluded from the labour force, this process of de-unionization appears less volatile (with peaks in 1950 and in the mid-1970s of 43%, and a subsequent drop). If only active union members are taken into account—that is excluding retired members, conscripts, and the disabled—one sees an almost constant decline from a peak of 42% in 1950.

  44. 44.

    Van den Berg (1995, Chap. 5).

  45. 45.

    Van de Vall (1963, pp. 101, 216–7).

  46. 46.

    Windmuller et al. (1987, p. 323).

  47. 47.

    Oudegeest (1914, p. 55) and Rimlinger (1982).

  48. 48.

    Berger (1936, pp. 276–92) and Suurhoff (1952).

  49. 49.

    Schrage and Nijhof (1992, p. 40). In 1938, an NVV official claimed union benefits had steadily declined, while government support had grown. See Kuypers and Schrage (1997). However, union unemployment benefits were the same in 1938 as they had been in, for example, 1934, both in absolute terms and as a percentage of average wages (see van der Veen and van Zanden 1984</CitationRef>, p. 228 and Schrage et al. 1989, p. 393). Unfortunately, no data are available on benefits in later years, nor on insurance conditions such as level of contributions or the duration of, and qualification for, entitlements.

  50. 50.

    Morren (1941, p. 86).

  51. 51.

    Harmsen et al. (1980, pp. 191–4).

  52. 52.

    Japenga and van der Velden (1992, p. 503). Commercial insurers had not been very profitable: between 1910 and 1930, 17 out of 29 went bankrupt. See Vonk (2012, p. 170). In the first half of the twentieth century, new and costly medical treatments such as X-rays and the use of radioactive materials came into use. See Vonk (2012, p. 168).

  53. 53.

    Staatsblad, 13 June 1963, p. 284, taking effect on 1 January 1965.

  54. 54.

    Fase (1982), Windmuller et al. (1987)—the original of which was in English: Windmuller (1969)—and Brug and Peer (1993).

  55. 55.

    It is not entirely clear what constitutes a collective agreement (CAO or collectieve arbeidsovereenkomst) and what constitutes a so-called company regulation (arbeidsreglement). In principle, the latter deal with minor labour conditions, unilaterally imposed by a company and governing such matters as lunch hours, drinking, or cursing. In practice, they sometimes contain provisions for matters normally dealt with under a collective agreement. The data refer only to what employers (and unions) called a collective agreement, and thus miss some of the collective labour agreements presented as company regulations. See Schrover (1991, pp. 13–5).

  56. 56.

    A 1950 report mentions, for example, the end or imminent end of such funds in the metal, cigar, textile, and shoe industries. A CBS report for 1954 records that average benefits under the Family Allowances Act were 1 guilder in 1947 and 1.4 guilders in 1954.

  57. 57.

    If one were to focus on other subgroups, male workers in the construction industry for example, one might well see even higher levels. In relation to this, it should be remembered that collective agreements were not the only source of welfare. Trade union insurance, social security laws, poor relief, company schemes, and micro-insurance by trade unions or friendly societies all operated in the field of welfare. Combined, these welfare arrangements covered significant sections of the population.

  58. 58.

    While the CBS data continued to give information on provisions relating to illness in collective agreements, they no longer stated the number of workers covered by each agreement. Hence it is not possible to extend the table to include the post-war years. To give an impression of the situation, the CBS report for 1950 makes it clear that many collective agreements stipulated that workers who were ill would receive wages—either in full or 80% of their normal wage—during the karenztime, and that afterwards statutory sick benefits would be supplemented. The report shows that the same happened in the event of industrial accidents.

  59. 59.

    Van Waarden (1985, esp. p. 250); see also van Zanden (1987, esp. p. 76) and Vijn (1993, esp. p. 104).

  60. 60.

    The following example relates to the sphere of labour conditions in general and not to social welfare in the narrow sense. In 1965, paper mill employers wanted continuous working shifts instead of the existing three shifts a day. This meant some workers would have to work at unsocial hours, and there was strong worker opposition. Trade unions were more understanding, as they accepted management’s argument that competition from Germany and Sweden made continuous shifts a necessity. The unions agreed, and many of their members resigned. By way of concession, employers accepted a longstanding union desire, namely for employers to subsidize the unions. Subsidies meant contributions could be reduced, which might persuade irate workers to remain in the union or help the union to attract non-unionized workers. Of course, it also implied unions becoming less dependent on their members. For this reason, the agreement was controversial among unions, as it was, too, among employers’ organizations, which felt uneasy about employers subsidizing unions. See Windmuller et al. (1987, pp. 315–9).

  61. 61.

    Quoted by Rutjens (1993, p. 51).

  62. 62.

    Fase (1982, p. 15). This process benefited workers without collective bargaining agreements; it was probably neutral for unionists, but it was problematic for unions as it deprived such agreements of their role in providing selective incentives.

  63. 63.

    Unfortunately, almost nothing is known about union pension schemes in the Netherlands, save that, as Table 4.1 has shown, it was a marginal phenomenon compared with other Dutch union welfare provisions. Due to the regularities of mortality patterns as captured in a life table and the irregularities of the business cycle, predicting the number of beneficiaries of old age pensions is much easier than predicting the number of those entitled to unemployment benefits. If, nonetheless, contributions to pension schemes prove actuarially unsound—for example, through carelessness or because of a marked rise in life expectancy—the ensuing financial strains easily become burdensome, as old age pensions are generally paid out for a longer period than unemployment benefits. See Hanson (1975, pp. 251–3), Musson (1976, p. 628), and Fukasawa (1997). See also, however, Thane (1976).

  64. 64.

    Harris (1972, p. 298) and Boyer (1988, pp. 320, 322, 332); see also Hanson (1975, p. 248).

  65. 65.

    Beveridge (1909, pp. 224–5). ‘Indefinitely’ is not to be taken literally: ‘of the 44 “principal” unions outside the cotton trade paying unemployment benefits in 1899, 27 made allowances for 20 consecutive weeks or more’. Ibid.

  66. 66.

    Webb and Webb (1897, p. 158).

  67. 67.

    Musson (1976, p. 628) and Boyer (1988, p. 329).

  68. 68.

    Beveridge (1909, p. 217); see also Boyer (1988, p. 323). For an example relating to modern US unions, see Freeman and Medoff (1984, pp. 65–6).

  69. 69.

    Whiteside (1987, p. 216).

  70. 70.

    Southall (1995, pp. 71, 81).

  71. 71.

    Whiteside (1980, p. 860) and idem (1983, pp. 167, 189–90).

  72. 72.

    Idem (1983).

  73. 73.

    Idem (1987, p. 213). In fact, much depended on the financial situation of a particular union and the applicability of provisions under state welfare legislation to the unionists concerned. The 1911 National Insurance Act was particularly ill-suited to cope with casual work, premised as it was on the notion of cyclical unemployment. Both structural underemployment as well as irregular work patterns would, in many cases, disqualify a worker from claiming state benefits. See idem (1979, 1980).

  74. 74.

    Gilbert (1993, p. 280).

  75. 75.

    Whiteside (1980, pp. 867–70) and idem (1987, pp. 216, 222).

  76. 76.

    Idem (1987, pp. 213, 227). Other factors were at work as well. Sectors of the economy with a tradition of union welfare schemes declined, while other sectors without such a tradition, and as a consequence with more to gain from state welfare schemes, prospered. Furthermore, union membership was extended to include more semi-skilled workers, probably more of a ‘bad risk’ in actuarial terms. Ibid., p. 218.

  77. 77.

    Ibid., p. 237.

  78. 78.

    Southall (1995, p. 71), with reference to Beveridge (1909, p. 263).

  79. 79.

    Whiteside (1979, p. 520) and idem (1983, pp. 117, 184ff.).

  80. 80.

    An issue difficult to determine at present is the extent to which individuals might belong to more than one fund. This is also relevant here because some trade union members might also have been affiliated to a non-trade union sickness fund, and if dual membership was tolerated (or unseen) they would not therefore have needed the same level of benefit in the event of illness as they needed if they were unemployed.

  81. 81.

    See van Empel (1995).

  82. 82.

    http://www.menzis.nl/web/Consumenten/Zorgverzekering/CollectieveZorgverzekering/ZorgcollectiefFNVMenzis (last accessed 14 June 2015).

  83. 83.

    The Onderlinge Waarborgmaatschappij Univé Noord Groningen B.A. See http://www.unive.nl/verzekeringen, last accessed 14 June 2015.

  84. 84.

    See https://www.freelancersunion.org, last accessed 14 June 2015, and van Grunsven (2011).

References

  • Ashenfelter, O., and Pencavel, J. H. (1969) ‘American Trade Union Growth: 1900–1960’ Quarterly Journal of Economics, 83, 434–48.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bain, G. S., and Elsheikh, F. (1976) Union Growth and the Business Cycle: An Econometric Analysis (Oxford).

    Google Scholar 

  • Berg, A. van den (1995) Trade Union Growth and Decline in the Netherlands (Amsterdam).

    Google Scholar 

  • Berger, J. A. (1936) Van armenzorg tot werklozenzorg (Amsterdam).

    Google Scholar 

  • Beveridge, W. H. (1909) Unemployment: A Problem of Industry (London).

    Google Scholar 

  • Boyer, G. R. (1988) ‘What Did Unions Do in Nineteenth-Century Britain?’ Journal of Economic History, 48, 319–32.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brug, L., and Peer, H. (eds) (1993) Collectief geregeld. Uit de geschiedenis van de CAO (Amsterdam).

    Google Scholar 

  • Bymholt, B. (1894) Geschiedenis der arbeidersbeweging in Nederland (Amsterdam).

    Google Scholar 

  • Centraal Bureau voor de Statistiek (2014) Leerlingen, deelnemers en studenten; onderwijssoort, vanaf 1900. Retrieved from http://statline.cbs.nl.

  • Centraal Bureau voor de Statistiek (1920–60) Overzicht van den omvang der Vakbeweging (The Hague).

    Google Scholar 

  • Cillekens, C. C., and Roebroeks, W. (1983) Werkloosheid en werk te Maastricht in de jaren dertig (Maastricht).

    Google Scholar 

  • CNV (1920–60) Verslag van het Christelijk Nationaal Vakverbond in Nederland (n.p.).

    Google Scholar 

  • Crouch, C. (1982) Trade Unions: The Logic of Collective Action (Glasgow).

    Google Scholar 

  • Directie van den Arbeid (1912) Onderzoek naar de in Nederland bestaande fondsen ter ondersteuning van arbeiders bij ziekte (The Hague).

    Google Scholar 

  • Emery, G., and Emery, H. (1999) Young Man’s Benefit: The Independent Order of Odd Fellows and Sickness Insurance in the United States and Canada 18601929 (Montreal).

    Google Scholar 

  • Empel, F. van (1995) ‘FNV wil uitkering leden zelf regelen’ NRC Handelsblad, 8 March.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fase, W. J. P. M. (1982) CAO-recht: schets van het recht met betrekking tot CAO’s (Alphen aan den Rijn).

    Google Scholar 

  • Freeman, R. B. and Medoff, J. L. (1984) What Do Unions Do? (New York).

    Google Scholar 

  • Fukasawa, K. (1997) ‘From Superannuation Benefit to State Old-Age Pensions: The Development of Trade Unionists’ Views on State Old-Age Pensions’ in A. Knotter, B. Altena, and D. Damsma (eds) Labour, Social Policy and the Welfare State (Amsterdam), 111–23.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gilbert, B. B. (1993) The Evolution of National Insurance in Great Britain: The Origins of the Welfare State (Aldershot).

    Google Scholar 

  • Goedhart, J. (1926) De ontwikkeling van de werkloosheidsverzekering in Nederland (Amsterdam).

    Google Scholar 

  • Groot, F. (1987) ‘“Het zou een janboel worden”: Steunfraude en haar bestrijding in Amsterdam 1930–1940’ Tijdschrift voor Sociale Geschiedenis, 13, 243–71.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grunsven, M. van. (2011) ‘Vakbond nieuwe stijl’ NRC Weekend, 18–19 June.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hanson, C. G. (1975, 1976) ‘Craft Unions, Welfare Benefits and the Case for Trade Union Law Reform, 1867–75’ Economic History Review, 28, 243–59, and 29, 631–5.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harmsen, G., and Reinalda, B. (1975) Voor de bevrijding van de arbeid: Beknopte geschiedenis van de Nederlandse vakbeweging (Nijmegen).

    Google Scholar 

  • Harmsen, G., Perry, J., and van Gelder, F. (1980) Mensenwerk: Industriële vakbonden op weg naar eenheid (Baarn).

    Google Scholar 

  • Harris, J. (1972) Unemployment and Politics: A Study in English Social Policy 1886–1914 (Oxford).

    Google Scholar 

  • Hechter, M., and Kanazawa, S. (1993) ‘Group Solidarity and Social Order in Japan’ Journal of Theoretical Politics, 5, 455–93.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Japenga, C. J., and van der Velden, H. F. (1992) ‘Het geneeskundige beroep en de regionale differentiatie in organisatie en financiering van de gezondheidszorg in Nederland (1900–1941): de casus Friesland’ Tijdschrift voor Sociale Geschiedenis, 18, 502–23.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jensma, G. T., and Vries, H. de (1997) Veranderingen in het hoger onderwijs in Nederland tussen 1815 en 1940 (Hilversum).

    Google Scholar 

  • Jonge, J. A. de (1968) De industrialisatie in Nederland tussen 1850 en 1914 (Amsterdam).

    Google Scholar 

  • Kuypers, I., and Schrage, P. (1997) ‘From Wage Bargaining Instrument to Compulsory Insurance Legislation: Government, Employer and Employee Organizations and Unemployment Insurance in the Netherlands 1861–1949’ in A. Knotter, B. Altena, and D. Damsma (eds) Labour, Social Policy and the Welfare State (Amsterdam).

    Google Scholar 

  • Leeuwen, M. H. D. van (1998a) ‘Armenzorg 1800–1912: erfenis van de Republiek’ in J. van Gerwen and M. H. D. van Leeuwen (eds) Studies over zekerheidsarrangementen. Risico’s, risicobestrijding en verzekeringen in Nederland vanaf de Middeleeuwen (Amsterdam and The Hague), 276–317.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leeuwen, M. H. D. van (1997a) ‘Trade Unions and the Provision of Welfare in the Netherlands, 1910–1960’ Economic History Review, 50, 764–91.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lijphart, A. (1968) The Politics of Accommodation, Pluralism and Democracy in the Netherlands (Berkeley).

    Google Scholar 

  • Mandemakers, C. A. (1999) ‘Onderwijsdeelname, 1870–1990’ in R. van der Bie and P. Dehing (eds) Nationaal goed. Feiten en cijfers over onze samenleving (ca.) 1800–1999 (Amsterdam), 179–97.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mannoury, J. (1985) ‘De ontwikkeling van het sociale verzekeringsstelsel’ in F. L. van Holthoon (ed) De Nederlandse samenleving sinds 1815 (Assen), 187–201.

    Google Scholar 

  • Morren, H. J. (1941) De werkloosheidsverzekering (Alphen aan den Rijn).

    Google Scholar 

  • Musson, A. E. (1976) ‘Craft Unions, Welfare Benefits and the Case for Trade Union Law Reform, 1867–75: A Comment’ Economic History Review, 29, 626–30.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nijhof, E., and Schrage, P. (1984) ‘Van bondslokaal tot steunloket: De vakbeweging als sociaal vangnet tijdens de economische crisis in Nederland (1929–1935)’ Amsterdams Sociologisch Tijdschrift, 11, 260–85.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nijhof, E., Schrage, P., and Sturkenboom, M. (1983) De geesel van onzen tijd: Een onderzoek naar werklozenbeleid en werkloosheidsbeleving in de jaren dertig te Utrecht (Leiden).

    Google Scholar 

  • NVV (1920–60) Verslag van den toestand en de verrichtingen van het Nederlandsch Verbond van Vakvereenigingen (Amsterdam).

    Google Scholar 

  • Olson, M. (1965) The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups (Cambridge).

    Google Scholar 

  • Oudegeest, J. (1914) Verzekering tegen werkloosheid (Amsterdam).

    Google Scholar 

  • Post, H. (1989) Pillarization: An Analysis of Dutch and Belgian Society (Aldershot).

    Google Scholar 

  • Recter, C. G. (1940) Armen en werkloozenzorg: Een onderzoek naar de ontwikkeling der armen- en werkloozenzorg in Twente en in het bijzonder Almelo (Almelo).

    Google Scholar 

  • Rimlinger, G. V. (1982) ‘The Historical Analysis of National Welfare Systems’ in R. Ransom, R. Sutch, and G.M. Walton (eds) Explorations in the New Economic History (New York), 149–67.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rooy, P. de (2002) Republiek van rivaliteiten. Nederland sinds 1813 (Amsterdam).

    Google Scholar 

  • Rooy, P. de (1983) ‘Armenzorg in Nederland’ in B. Kruithof et al. (eds) Geschiedenis van opvoeding en onderwijs (Nijmegen), 96–104.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rooy, P. de (1979) Werklozenzorg en werkloosheidsbestrijding 1917–1940 (Amsterdam).

    Google Scholar 

  • Rutjens, R. (1993) ‘“Wonderbaar werkend geneesmiddel”. De CAO in het katholiek sociaal denken’ in L. Brug and H. Peer (eds) Collectief geregeld. Uit de geschiedenis van de CAO (Amsterdam), 41–56.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schrage, P., and Nijhof, E. (1992) ‘Een lange sisser en een late knal?: De ontwikkeling van de Nederlandse werkloosheidsverzekering in West-Europees perspectief: Een terreinverkenning’ in W. P. Blockmans and L. A. van der Valk (eds) Van particuliere naar openbare zorg en terug? (Amsterdam), 31–52.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schrage, P., Nijhof, E., and Wielsma, P. (1989) ‘Inkomensontwikkeling van werkenden en werklozen in Nederland, 1913–1939’ Tijdschrift voor Sociale Geschiedenis, 14, 347–94.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schrover, M. (1991) Het vette, het zoete en het wederzijds profijt (Amsterdam).

    Google Scholar 

  • Schwitters, R. J. S. (1991) De risico’s van de arbeid: Het ontstaan van de Ongevallenwet 1901 in sociologisch perspectief (Groningen).

    Google Scholar 

  • Soeteman, A. (1962) 150 jaar sociale zorg in Vlaardingen 1795–1945 (Voorburg).

    Google Scholar 

  • Southall, H. R. (1995) ‘Neither State Nor Market: Early Welfare Benefits in Britain’ in B. Palier (ed) Comparing Social Welfare Systems in Europe vol. 1. The Oxford Conference (Paris), 59–92.

    Google Scholar 

  • Staatscommissie (1914) Over de werkloosheid (The Hague).

    Google Scholar 

  • Suurhoff, J. G. (1952) Zo werkt de Werkloosheidswet (Amsterdam).

    Google Scholar 

  • Thane, P. (1976) ‘Craft Unions, Welfare Benefits and the Case for Trade Union Law Reform, 1867–75: A Comment’ Economic History Review, 29, 617–25.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tijn, T. van (1976) ‘A Contribution to the Scientific Study of the History of the Trade Unions’ International Review of Social History, 21, 212–39.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vall, M. van de (1963) De vakbeweging in een welvaartsstaat (Meppel).

    Google Scholar 

  • Veen, D. J. van der, and Zanden, J. L. van (1984) ‘Real-Wage Trends and Consumer Patterns in the Netherlands, c. 1870–1940’ in P. Scholtens (ed) Real Wages in 19th and 20th Century Europe (New York), 205–28.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vijn, M. (1993) ‘De CAO, sociaal-rechtelijk beschouwd’ in L. Brug and H. Peer (eds) Collectief geregeld. Uit de geschiedenis van de CAO (Amsterdam), 97–108.

    Google Scholar 

  • Visser, J. (1989) European Trade Unions in Figures (Deventer).

    Google Scholar 

  • Vonk, R. A. A. (2012) ‘In it for the money? Insurers, Sickness Funds and the Dominance of Not-for-Profit Health Insurance in the Netherland’, in B. Harris (ed), Welfare and Old Age in Europe and North-America: The Development of Social Insurance. Perspectives in Economic and Social History (London), 167–87.

    Google Scholar 

  • Waarden, F. van (1985) ‘Regulering en belangenorganisaties van ondernemers’ in F. L. van Holthoon (ed) De Nederlandse samenleving sinds 1815 (Assen).

    Google Scholar 

  • Webb, S., and Webb, B. (1897) Industrial Democracy (London).

    Google Scholar 

  • Western, B. (1995) ‘Union Decline in Eighteen Advanced Capitalist Countries’ American Sociological Review, 60, 179–201.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Western, B. (1993) ‘Postwar Unionization in Eighteen Advanced Capitalist Countries’ American Sociological Review, 58, 266–82.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Whiteside, N. (1987) ‘Social Welfare and Industrial Relations 1914–1939’ in C. Wrigley (ed) A History of British Industrial Relations (Brighton), 211–42.

    Google Scholar 

  • Whiteside, N. (1983) ‘Private Agencies for Public Purposes: Some New Perspectives on Policy Making in Health Insurance between the Wars’ Journal of Social Policy, 12, 165–93.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Whiteside, N. (1980) ‘Welfare Insurance and the Unions during the First World War’ Historical Journal, 23, 857–74.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Whiteside, N. (1979) ‘Welfare Insurance and Casual Labour: A Study of Administrative Intervention in Industrial Employment 1906–1926’ Economic History Review, 32, 507–22.

    Google Scholar 

  • Windmuller, J. P. (1969) Labor Relations in the Netherlands (Ithaca).

    Google Scholar 

  • Windmuller, J. P., Galan, C. de, and Zweeden, A. F. van (1987) Arbeidsverhoudingen in Nederland (Utrecht).

    Google Scholar 

  • Wintle, M. (2000) An Economic and Social History of the Netherlands 1800–1920 (Cambridge).

    Google Scholar 

  • Zanden, J. L. van (1987) De industrialisatie in Amsterdam 1825–1914 (Bergen).

    Google Scholar 

  • Zanden, J. L. van, and Riel, A. van (2000) Nederland 1780–1914. Staat, instituties en economische ontwikkeling (Amsterdam and Meppel).

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Copyright information

© 2016 The Author(s)

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

van Leeuwen, M.H.D. (2016). The Rise and Decline of Modern Trade Union Insurance, 1900–65. In: Mutual Insurance 1550-2015. Palgrave Studies in the History of Finance. Palgrave Macmillan, London. https://doi.org/10.1057/978-1-137-53110-0_4

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/978-1-137-53110-0_4

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Palgrave Macmillan, London

  • Print ISBN: 978-1-137-53109-4

  • Online ISBN: 978-1-137-53110-0

  • eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics