Skip to main content

Political Economy of Liquidity: The European Economic and Monetary Union

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
The Palgrave Handbook of Political Economy

Abstract

The European Economic and Monetary Union (EMU) is examined according to a network (complex-system) approach. Problems of idiosyncratic, endogenous and systemic risks are addressed. In this perspective, six economic paradoxes of the Euro zone are identified: inflation, liquidity, saving, de-leveraging, central bank balance sheet independence from domestic government debt, and bank capital. They are closely intertwined, but separately identifiable: a common thread is the fallacy of composition. All paradoxes defy current economic policies of EMU, which are critically assessed: suggested lines of an in-depth rethink are predicated by making reference to an enlarged macroprudential policy paradigm. Finally, the concept of liquidity in EMU is critically examined.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 349.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD 449.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    The implications of the Heisenberg indeterminacy principle for the methodology of research in economics are examined in Masera (2010).

  2. 2.

    Among other things, this implies that monetary assets can no longer be easily identified in terms of: (i) stability vis-à-vis prices and income and (ii) aggregate demand for money functions (Ewe-Ghee and Subramanian 2003).

  3. 3.

    Appendix 1 provides an attempt to throw light on this crucial issue, also with reference to the role of the ECB in respect of Lender of Last Resort (LOLR).

  4. 4.

    There is a significant literature on the need to address the debt-equity tax bias. Reference can be made to IMF (de Mooij 2011) and EC contributions (Fatica et al. 2012).

  5. 5.

    Evidence—selected here from research undertaken inside central banks—on the changed environment is obtained by comparing the conclusions by Angeloni et al. (2002), with the new findings of many authors: Bassett and Covas (2013), Angelini et al. (2014), Aiyar et al. (2014), Bassett et al. (2014), Bridges et al. (2014), Labonne and Lamé (2014), Uluc and Wieladek (2015), Alessandri and Panetta (2015).

  6. 6.

    For the application of this analytical framework to economics, see Haldane (2015) and Battiston et al. (2016).

  7. 7.

    Haldane (2015) developed an analytical framework to assess the implications of complexity theory to outline an overall architecture of public economic policies.

  8. 8.

    In the UK, the Bank of England has been tasked with the simultaneous pursuit of monetary, micro- and macro-prudential policies (Bank of England 2015). In the Euroarea, the institutional problems do not appear to be settled, as cogently argued by Ramos Munoz (2016).

  9. 9.

    On these points, see, for instance, Goodhart and Schoenmaker (2014) and Appendix 1.

  10. 10.

    On these points, see also Lin (2016). Figures 6 and 7 highlight the poor performance in terms of investment and of factor productivity. The two elements are clearly intertwined, as evidenced by many studies and by the Juncker Plan (2015) itself.

  11. 11.

    The widening “real” gap with the USA is also documented in an IMF working paper (Lin 2016), where it is, in particular, highlighted that “In PPP terms, nominal GDP per capita in the euro area is now nearly $15,000 below that in the USA, the highest gap since the start of EMU”.

  12. 12.

    It is hard not to agree with a key observer as Otmar Issing, who recently argued that, instead, “since EMU was created no progress towards political union has been made – or even really attempted” (Issing 2015).

  13. 13.

    For an interesting law and economic policy framework to EMU, see Capriglione and Sacco Ginevri (2016).

  14. 14.

    For a survey of the complex economic governance framework in the EMU, see Donatelli et al. (2016) and Cardinale et al. (2017).

  15. 15.

    Small banks also suffer from the very high operational costs of implementation and compliance to the complex and ever-changing regulations (Dombret 2016).

  16. 16.

    See Tarullo (2014), Yellen (2014, 2015) and Hoskins and Labonte (2015).

  17. 17.

    On the two models, see Cohen-Eliya and Porat (2010). Both analytical frameworks can be viewed in the realm of the Aristotelian equity principle.

  18. 18.

    The rational for the one-size-fits-approach to level 1 capital legislation on banks in the EU is explained in EC (2013). Counterarguments are developed in Masera (2013).

  19. 19.

    Important contributions to the debate on proportionality and complexity in EU banking regulation are offered by Dombret (2016)—who underlined the support recently voiced by Minister Wolfgang Schäuble to the principle of proportionality—and Hadjiemmanuil (2016).

  20. 20.

    The view of an inevitable secular stagnation predicated on the non-availability of valuable capital accumulation options is contradicted by the strong evidence which shows that ample opportunities exist for social/private investment-grade projects (notably in innovation—including Industry 4.0—, in human capital and in the environment). See EIB (2016) and Invest Europe (2016).

  21. 21.

    On these points, see EIB (2016, pp. 75–88).

  22. 22.

    On these points, see, for instance, Brunnermeier and Pedersen (2009), Cont (2012), and Danielsson (2013).

  23. 23.

    Both authors considered it necessary to give LOLR liquidity powers to the Bank of England to help preserve the good functioning of the monetary/credit transmission process in case of threat because of illiquidity of commercial banks.

  24. 24.

    For a different approach, see Lautenschläger (2016).

  25. 25.

    The yield from these operations and the corresponding possible solvency risk are however largely transferred back to the central banks of the countries whose debt is bought. The dynamic relationship between market liquidity and credit risk in government bond markets is examined in Pelizzon et al. (2014) and de Pooter et al. (2015).

References

  • Agence Europe. 1990. Mitterrand and Kohl urge European Political Union, April 20.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aiyar, S., C. Calomiris, and T. Wieladek. 2014. How Does Credit Supply Respond to Monetary Policy and Bank Minimum Capital Requirements? Working Paper 508, Bank of England, September.

    Google Scholar 

  • Alessandri, P., and F. Panetta. 2015. Prudential Policy at Times of Stagnation: A View from the Trenches. Questioni di Economia e Finanza. Occasional Papers 300, December.

    Google Scholar 

  • Allard, C., P. Koeva Brooks, J.C. Bluedorn, F. Bornhorst, K. Christopherson, F. Ohnsorge, T. Poghosyan, and an IMF Staff Team. 2013. Toward a Fiscal Union for the Euro Area. IMF Staff Discussion Note, SDN/13/09, September.

    Google Scholar 

  • Angelini, P., S. Neri, and F. Panetta. 2014. The Interaction Between Capital Requirements and Monetary Policy. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 46 (6): 1073–1112.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Angeloni, I., A. Kashyap, B. Mojon, and D. Terlizzese. 2002. Monetary Transmission in the Euro Area: Where Do We Stand? Working Paper Series, No. 114, European Central Bank, January.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bagehot, W. 1873. Lombard Street: A Description of the Money Market. London: Henry S. King & Co.

    Google Scholar 

  • Banca d’Italia. 2013. Italy Non-paper on Bail-in, Working Document 52, Crisis Management & Bank Resolution Directive Working Party on Financial Services, March 12.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bank of England. 2015. One Bank Research Agenda Discussion Paper, February.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bassett, W.F., and F. Covas. 2013. A New Look at the Relationship Between Capital Constraints and Bank Lending. Working Paper, Federal Reserve Board, Washington, DC.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bassett, W.F., et al. 2014. Changes in Bank Lending Standards and the Macroeconomy. Journal of Monetary Economics 62 (C): 23–40.

    Google Scholar 

  • Battiston, S., J.D. Farmer, A. Flache, D. Garlaschelli, A.G. Haldane, H. Heesterbeek, C. Hommes, C. Jaeger, R. May, and M. Scheffer. 2016. Complex Systems. Complexity Theory and Financial Regulation. Science 351 (6275): 818–819.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bordes, C., and L. Clerc. 2010. The Art of Central Banking at the ECB and the Separation Principle. Working Paper, No. 290, Banque de France, August.

    Google Scholar 

  • Borio, C. 2016. On-the-Record Remarks, BIS Quarterly Review, March 2016—Media Briefing, March 4.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bridges, J., D. Gregory, M. Nielsen, S. Pezzini, A. Radia, and M. Spaltro. 2014. The Impact of Capital Requirements on Bank Lending. Staff Working Paper 486, Bank of England, London, January.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brunnermeier, M.K., and L.H. Pedersen. 2009. Market Liquidity and Funding Liquidity. The Review of Financial Studies 22 (6): 2201–2238.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Calomiris, C.W. 2015. What’s Wrong with Prudential Bank Regulation and How to Fix It. Testimony Before the U.S. House Committee on Financial Services, July 23. Available at: http://financialservices.house.gov/uploadedfiles/hhrg-114-ba00-wstate-ccalomiris-20150723.pdf.

  • Capriglione, F., and Ginevri A. Sacco. 2016. Politics and Finance in the European Union. The Reasons for a Difficult Encounter. Milano: Wolters Kluwer Italia.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cardinale, I., and R. Scazzieri. 2014. The Political Economy of the Eurozone: Crisis and Prospects. Accademia delle Scienze dell’Istituto di Bologna, Classe di Scienze Morali, Rendiconti (Years 2012–2013), 151–160.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cardinale, I., and R. Scazzieri. 2016. Structural Liquidity: The Money-Industry Nexus. Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 39: 46–53.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cardinale, I., D. Coffman, and R. Scazzieri. 2017. Framing the Political Economy of the Eurozone: Structural Heuristics for Analysis and Policy. In The Political Economy of the Eurozone, ed. I. Cardinale, D. Coffman, and R. Scazzieri, 483–551. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Cohen-Eliya, M., and I. Porat. 2010. American Balancing and German Proportionality: The Historical Origins. International Journal of Constitutional Law 8: 263–286.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Constâncio, V. 2015. Presentation at the 2015 US Monetary Policy Forum Panel Discussion on Central Banking with Large Balance Sheets. New York, February 27.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cont, R. 2012. Modeling Black Swans. Correlation, Contagion and Endogenous Risk. Available at: http://proba.jussieu.fr/pageperso/ramacont.

  • Cour-Thimann, P., and B. Winkler. 2012. The ECB’s Non-standard Monetary Policy Measures: The Role of Institutional Factors and Financial Structure. Oxford Review of Economic Policy 28: 765–803.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crockett, A.D. 2000. Marrying the Micro- and Macro-prudential Dimensions of Financial Stability. Remarks Before the Eleventh International Conference of Banking Supervisors, Basel, September 20–21.

    Google Scholar 

  • Danielsson, J. 2013. Global Financial Systems: Stability and Risk, Chapter 4 Liquidity. London: Pearson Education.

    Google Scholar 

  • Danielsson, J., and H.S. Shin. 2003. Endogenous Risk. In Modern Risk Management—A History, ed. P. Field. London: Risk Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Danielsson, J., H. Shin, and J. Zigrand. 2011. Endogenous and Systemic Risk, August. Available at:  http://www.riskresearch.org.

  • de Angelo, H., and R.M. Stulz. 2013. Why High Leverage is Optimal for Banks. NBER Working Paper Series, WP 19139, June.

    Google Scholar 

  • de Larosière, J. 2013. The Trade-Off Between Bank Regulation and Economic Growth. Central Banking Journal, February 28.

    Google Scholar 

  • de Larosière, J., L. Balcerowicz, O. Issing, R. Masera, C. McCarthy, L. Nyberg, J. Pérez, and O. Ruding. 2009. The High-Level Group on Financial Supervision in the EU: Report, Brussels, February 25.

    Google Scholar 

  • de Mooij, R.A. 2011. Tax Biases to Debt Finance: Assessing the Problem, Finding Solutions. IMF Staff Discussion Note, SDN/11/11, May 3.

    Google Scholar 

  • de Pooter, M., R.F. Martin, and S. Pruitt. 2015. The Liquidity Effects of Official Bond Market Intervention. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, International Finance Discussion Papers, 1138, July.

    Google Scholar 

  • Diamond, D.W., and P.H. Dybvig. 1983. Bank Runs, Deposit Insurance, and Liquidity. The Journal of Political Economy 91 (3): 401–419.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dodd, C., and B. Frank. 2010. The Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act. US Congress, July 21.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dombret, A. 2016. Cui Bono? Complex Regulation and Its Consequences. Speech at the 20th Banking Symposium of the European Center for Financial Services at the University of Duisburg-Essen, Duisburg, September 7. Available at: http://www.bis.org/review/r160915b.pdf.

  • Donatelli, L., A. Zoppè, and D. Paternoster. 2016. Institutions and Bodies in the Economic and Monetary Union. Directorate General for Internal Policies, European Parliament, PE 574.388, February.

    Google Scholar 

  • Draghi, M. 2014. Introductory Remarks at the EP’s Economic and Monetary Committee. Speech, ECB, September 22.

    Google Scholar 

  • Draghi, M. 2015. Hearing at the European Parliament’s Economic and Monetary Affairs Committee. March 23.

    Google Scholar 

  • Draghi, M. 2016a. Addressing the Causes of Low Interest Rates. In Introductory Speech at the Annual Meeting of the Asian Development Bank, Frankfurt am Main, May 2.

    Google Scholar 

  • Draghi, M. 2016b. Working Together for Growth in Europe. In Introductory Remarks at Deutscher Bundestag, Berlin, September 28.

    Google Scholar 

  • Economic Insight. 2015. What Is the Relationship Between Public and Private Investment in Science, Research and Innovation. London, April.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eggertsson, G.B., and P. Krugman. 2012. Debt, Deleveraging, and the Liquidity Trap: A Fisher-Minsky-Koo Approach. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 127 (3): 1469–1513.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • European Central Bank (ECB). 2002. Developments in Banks’ Liquidity Profile and Management, Frankfurt am Main, May.

    Google Scholar 

  • European Central Bank (ECB). 2016. Economic Bulletin 2: 75–88.

    Google Scholar 

  • European Commission. 2013. Capital Requirements—CRD IV/CRR—Frequently Asked Questions. MEMO/13/690, Brussels, July 16.

    Google Scholar 

  • European Commission. 2015. Commission Issues Guidance to Encourage Structural Reforms and Investment. Strasburg, January 13.

    Google Scholar 

  • European Investment Bank (EIB). 2016. Investment and Investment Finance in Europe, Luxembourg.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ewe-Ghee, L., and S.S. Subramanian. 2003. Factors Underlying the Definition of Broad Money: An Examination of Recent U.S. Monetary Statistics and Practices of Other Countries. IMF Working Paper, WP/03/62, March.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fatica, S., T. Hemmelgarn, and G. Nicodème. 2012. The Debt-Equity Tax Bias: Consequences and Solutions. European Commission Taxation Papers, Working Paper 33.

    Google Scholar 

  • Federal Ministry of Finance. 2015. Germany’s Federal Debt Brake. Berlin, March.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gaiotti, E. 2013. Credit Availability and Investment: Lessons from the  “Great Recession” . European Economic Review 59 (C): 212–227.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Galbraith, J.K. 1958. The Affluent Society. New York and Toronto: New American Library.

    Google Scholar 

  • Garonna, P., and E. Reviglio (eds.). 2015. Investing in Long-Term Europe: Re-launching Fixed, Network and Social Infrastructure. Rome: Luiss-FeBAF.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goodhart, C.A.E. 2014. The Use of Macroprudential Instruments. In Macroprudentialism, Vox eBook, ed. D. Schoenmaker. Available at: voxeu.org.

  • Goodhart, C.A.E., and D. Schoenmaker. 2014. The ECB as Lender of Last resort? VOX CEPR’s Policy Portal, October 23.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gorton, G. 2010. Slapped by the Invisible Hand: The Panic of 2007 (Financial Management Association Survey and Synthesis). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hadjiemmanuil, C. 2016. Banking Union and the Debate on Proportionality. Paper presented at the Conference on “Reflections on the Design and Implementation of the European Banking Union”, Bologna, September 17.

    Google Scholar 

  • Haldane, A.G. 2015. On Microscopes and Telescopes, Speech Given at Lorentz Centre Workshop on Socio-Economic Complexity. Leiden, March 27.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hanson, S.G., A.K. Kashyap, and J.C. Stein. 2011. A Macroprudential Approach to Financial Regulation. Journal of Economic Perspectives 25 (1): 3–28.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Helbing, D. (2010). Systemic Risks in Society and Economics. In IRGC Report “The Emergence of Risks: Contributing Factors”, October.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hicks, J.R. 1939. Value and Capital. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hicks, J.R. 1967. Critical Essays in Monetary Theory. Oxford: Clarendon Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hicks, J.R. 1974. The Crisis in Keynesian Economics. Oxford: Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hoskins, S.M., and M. Labonte. 2015. An Analysis of the Regulatory Burden on Small Banks. US Congressional Research Service, April 22.

    Google Scholar 

  • International Monetary Fund (IMF). 2008. Monetary and Financial Statistics Compilation Guide, Washington, DC.

    Google Scholar 

  • Invest Europe. 2016. Europe’s Economic Foundations: Investing in Infrastructure, Invest Europe Briefing, November.

    Google Scholar 

  • Issing, O. 2008. The Birth of the Euro. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Issing, O. 2015. What’s the Key to Making Europe’s Monetary Union Work? World Economic Forum, September 29. Retrieved from http://www.weforum.org/agenda/2015/09/whats-the-key-to-making-europes-monetary-union-work/.

  • Juncker, J.C. 2015. Investment Plan. In Speech at the EIB Conference “Investment Plan for Europe”, Luxembourg.

    Google Scholar 

  • Juncker, J.C., D. Tusk, J. Dijsselbloem, M. Draghi, and M.C. Schulz. 2015. Completing Europe’s Economic and Monetary Union. Report, European Commission, Brussels, June 22.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keynes, J.M. 1930. A Treatise on Money. London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keynes, J.M. 1936. The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money. London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kohl, H. 1991. Statement to the Bundestag, November 6.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krugman, P. 2016. The Cases for Public Investment. The New York Times, February 27.

    Google Scholar 

  • Labonne, C., and G. Lamé. 2014. Credit Growth and Bank Capital Requirements: Binding or Not? Document de Travail, 481, Banque de France, Paris, July.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lamandini, M., and M.D. Ramos. 2015. The Single Supervisory Mechanism (SSM) and the Single Resolution Mechanism (SRM). In European Financial Law, ed. M. Lamandini and D. Ramos Munoz. Bologna: Bonomo Editore.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lautenschläger, S. 2016. Monetary Policy in Uncertain Times—The European Central Bank and the Crisis. Speech at a Parliamentary Evening, Strasbourg, September 13.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lin, H. 2016. Risks of Stagnation in the Euro Area. IMF Working Paper, WP/16/9, January.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lucas, E.L. 1990. Liquidity and Interest Rates. Journal of Economic Theory 50: 237–264.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maddaloni, A., and J.-L. Peydro. 2013. Monetary Policy, Macroprudential Policy, and Banking Stability: Evidence from the Euro Area. International Journal of Central Banking 9 (1): 121–169.

    Google Scholar 

  • Markowitz, H. 1952. Portfolio Selection. The Journal of Finance 7 (1): 77–91.

    Google Scholar 

  • Masera, R. 2010. Saggi Sulla Metodologia Della Ricerca in Economia. Roma: Gangemi editore.

    Google Scholar 

  • Masera, R. 2012. Risk Regulation and Supervision of Financial Systems: US and Eurozone Solutions. ZOeR 67: 251–280.

    Google Scholar 

  • Masera, R. 2013. US Basel III Final Rule on Banks’ Capital Requirements: A Different-Size-Fits-All Approach. PSL Quarterly Review 66 (267): 387–402.

    Google Scholar 

  • Masera, R. 2014. CRR/CRD IV: The Trees and the Forest. PSL Quarterly Review 67 (271): 381–422.

    Google Scholar 

  • Masera, R. 2015a. Macro Prudential Policy as a Reference for Economic Policies: A Hicksian Perspective. In Convegno Accademia Nazionale dei Lincei “Between Theory and Policy: Political Economy of Crises Trade-Off”, Rome, October 27. Available at: http://www.lincei.it/files/centro_linceo/Masera_20151027.pdf.

  • Masera, R. 2015b. The Capital Markets Union and the Elusive Goal of a ‛Genuine’ Economic and Monetary Union. Law and Economics Yearly Review 4, Part 2: 215–235.

    Google Scholar 

  • Masera, R. 2016a. Banking Regulation and Supervision: Selected Essays. Rome-Paris: Guglielmo Marconi University-Sciences Po.

    Google Scholar 

  • Masera, R. 2016b. Dalle buone infrastrutture il rilancio della crescita. Paper Astrid 238 (2).

    Google Scholar 

  • Masera, R., and G. Mazzoni. 2011. Towards a New Architecture for Financial Regulation. Reform of the Risk Capital Standard (RCS) and Systemically Important Financial Institutions (SIFIs). In Recovery After the Crisis: Perspective and Policies, ed. L. Paganetto. Saarbrücken: VDM Verlag Dr. Müller.

    Google Scholar 

  • Masera, R., and G. Mazzoni. 2016. On the Non-neutrality of the Financing Policy and the Capital Regulation of Banking Firms. Studies in Economics and Finance 33 (4): 466–487. https://doi.org/10.1108/SEF-09-2014-0179.

  • Mazzoni, G. 2016. Banks’ Stability and the Implications of Capital and Liquidity Requirements: A Contingent Claim Analysis (CCA). Luiss University Working Paper, October 5.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nikolaou, K. 2009. Liquidity (Risk) Concepts. Definitions and Interactions. ECB Working Paper Series 1008.

    Google Scholar 

  • Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development. 2016. OECD Compendium of Productivity Indicators 2016, Paris, May 26.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ostry, J.D., P. Loungani, and D. Furceri. 2016. Neoliberalism: Oversold? Finance & Development 53 (2): 1–8.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pabst, A. 2017. Political Economy and the Constitution of Europe’s Polity: Pathways for the Common Currency Beyond Ordo-Liberal and Neo-functionalist Models. In The Political Economy of the Eurozone, ed. I. Cardinale, D. Coffman, and R. Scazzieri, 183–215. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Paganetto, L. 2015. Revitalizing Anaemic Europe. In Executive Summary—Report 2014—Revitalizing Anaemic Europe, ed. L. Paganetto, 11–14. Rome: Eurilink.

    Google Scholar 

  • Panetta, F. 2016. Central Banking in the XXI Century: Never Say Never. In Remarks at SUERF/BAFFI CAREFIN Centre Conference “Central Banking and Monetary Policy: Which Will Be the New Normal?”, Milan, April 14.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pástor, L., and R.F. Stambaugh. 2003. Liquidity Risk and Expected Stock Returns. The Journal of Political Economy 111 (3): 642–685.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Patinkin, D. 1958. Liquidity Preference and Loanable Funds: Stock and Flow Analysis. Economica New Series 25 (100): 300–318.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pelizzon, L., M.G. Subrahmanyam, D. Tomio, and J. Uno. 2014. Sovereign Credit Risk, Liquidity, and ECB Intervention: Deus ex Machina? Available at: https://www.ecb.europa.eu/events/pdf/conferences/140908/pelizzon.pdf?2503876c7921494035971af2497f6a35.

  • Persaud, A.D. 2016. What Is Causing Flash Crashes? Prospect, December 30. Available at: http://www.prospectmagazine.co.uk/economics-and-finance/what-is-causing-flash-crashes.

  • Praet, P. 2015. Presentation at BVI Asset Management. Frankfurt: ECB, October 1.

    Google Scholar 

  • Prescott, E.C. 2006. Lecture at Trinity University in San Antonio. In Lives of the Laureates, Twenty-Three Nobel Economists, ed. R.W. Spencer and D.A. Macpherson, 2014, 6th ed. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Quadrio Curzio, A. 2017. Eurobonds for EMU Stability and Structural Growth. In The Political Economy of the Eurozone, ed. I. Cardinale, D. Coffman, and R. Scazzieri, 395–434. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Ramos Munoz, D. 2016. Reconciling Monetary Policy, Financial Stability, Prudential Mandates and Fundamental Rights: The ECB in ‘Unchartered Waters’? Paper presented at the Conference on “Reflections on the Design and Implementation of the European Banking Union”, Bologna, September 17.

    Google Scholar 

  • Roncaglia, A. 2013. Hyman Minsky’s Monetary Production Economy. PSL Quarterly Review 66 (265): 77–94.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scazzieri, R. 2015. The Medium-Term Approach to Economic Crises: A Framework. Convegno Accademia Nazionale dei Lincei ‘Between Theory and Policy: Political Economy of Crises’, Rome, October 27. Retrieved from http://www.lincei.it/files/centro_linceo/Scazzieri_20151027.pdf.

  • Sinn, H.W. 2012. The Green Paradox. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz, J.E. 2013. Stable Growth in an Era of Crises: Learning from Economic Theory and History. Ekonomi-tek 2 (1): 1–39.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sylos Labini, P. 1998. Inflazione, Disoccupazione e Banca Centrale: Temi per una Riconsiderazione Critica. Moneta e Credito 203: 363–374.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tarullo, D.K. 2014. Rethinking the Aims of Prudential Regulation. In Speech at the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago Bank Structure Conference, Chicago, Illinois, May 8.

    Google Scholar 

  • Thornton, H. 1802. An Enquiry into the Nature and Effects of the Paper Credit of Great Britain. New York: Reprints of Economic Classics (1965).

    Google Scholar 

  • Uluc, A., and T. Wieladek. 2015. Capital Requirements, Risk Shifting and the Mortgage Market. Staff Working Paper 572, Bank of England, London, December.

    Google Scholar 

  • Valla, N., T. Brand, and S. Doisy. 2014. A New Architecture for Public Investment in Europe: The Eurosystem of Investment Banks and the Fede Fund. CEPII Policy Brief, 4, July.

    Google Scholar 

  • Visco, V. 2014. “Audizione” presso la VI Commissione della Camera dei Deputati sulle prospettive della politica tributaria e del settore bancario, nel quadro dell’euro e in vista del prossimo semestre di Presidenza italiana dell’Unione Europea, Roma, 26 febbraio.

    Google Scholar 

  • Visco, I. 2016. Fact-Finding Inquiry on the Italian Banking and Financial System and the Protection of Savings, also Regarding Supervision, Crisis Resolution and European Deposit Insurance. Testimonial of the Governor of the Bank of Italy at the Italian Senate 6th Standing Committee (Finance and Treasury), Rome, April 19.

    Google Scholar 

  • Watanabe, M. 2003. A Model of Stochastic Liquidity. WFA 2003 and EFA 2003 Meetings. Available at: http://students.som.yale.edu/Phd/mw239/research/Stochastic_Liquidity.pdf.

  • Weidmann, J. 2016. Solidità e solidarietà nell’Unione monetaria. Discorso presso l’Ambasciata tedesca a Roma, 26 Aprile.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yellen, J.L. 2009. A Minsky Meltdown: Lessons for Central Bankers. Presentation to the 18th Annual Hyman P. Minsky Conference on the State of the U.S. and World Economies “Meeting the Challenges of the Financial Crisis”, Levy Economics Institute of Bard College, New York City, April 16.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yellen, J.L. 2014. Tailored Supervision of the Community Banks. Speech at the Independent Community Bankers of America 2014 Washington Policy Summit, Washington, DC, May 1.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yellen, J.L. 2015. Improving the Oversight of Large Financial Institutions. Speech at the Citizens Budget Commission, New York, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, March 3.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Rainer Masera .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendix 1

Appendix 1

1.1 Liquidity: The Difficulty of Theorising a Will-o’-the-Wisp

The concept and the term of liquidity have been used in the literature in innumerable not necessarily consistent ways. It is not even clear whether liquidity represents a flow or a stock variable and whether different definitions apply to different economic agents.

Let us start with the classic Keynesian approach to liquidity (although the term long precedes Keynes). Reference should not be made to the General Theory (1936), where the analysis of liquidity preference was introduced, money was viewed as the liquid asset, and the liquidity trap situation became a centrepiece of macroeconomic analysis. It is instead necessary to go back to the Treatise (1930, vol. II, p. 67): one asset is more liquid than another if (i) it is more certainly realisable (convertible into money) with a regular market price at short notice (i.e. marketable) and (ii) without loss. Marketability is a necessary but not sufficient condition for liquidity: marketable assets possess varying degrees of liquidity, while all liquid assets are marketable; their additional key feature is the possibility of liquidating them without incurring in abnormally low prices. It is the latter element which is key in assessing the liquidity spectrum.

It is clear from the above that the use of liquidity in the sense of referring to “moneyness” that different securities are supposed to possess in different degrees is confusing and should be avoided. All securities which can be used for payments functions should be classified as monetary assets (Lucas 1990); it remains true that money and securities with values fairly stable in terms of money represent liquid assets.

Asset liquidity can also be analysed through the asset portfolio selection models (Markowitz 1952), where a key role is played by the Treasury bill market and its corresponding interest rate (the risk-free rate). The interaction between asset portfolio selection and liquidity analysis is very complex (Hicks 1967). Beyond the common argument that the degree of liquidity is a relevant pricing factor for securities (positive premium for holding less liquid securities), attention is drawn to the relevant literature, notably on liquidity betas (Pástor and Stambaugh 2003). To recall, portfolio selection analyses asset choice under uncertainty:

$$r_{a} = r_{f} + \beta_{a} \cdot \left( {r_{m} - r_{f} } \right)$$
(1)

where ra = return of asset a; rf = time value of money = risk-free rate \(\cong\) Treasury bill rate; rm = return on the market portfolio, and βa indicates the risk of asset a compared to the market. The Treasury bill is, in general, a very liquid asset. In the Euroarea imperfect monetary union, its liquidity can however become questionable because of insolvency risk of the sovereign debt of the issuing country. The ECB Quantitative Easing (QE), negative interest rates market interventions, can eliminate/lower the fears of insolvency, but paradoxically reduce its marketability/liquidity.

The following elementary table offers a representation of the various elements introduced so far by making explicit reference to a balance sheet (and, therefore, stock) approach and by a restricting analysis to assets in the financial sector. Assets are, therefore, viewed from the perspective of financial instruments held by economic agents. They could be equally defined as liabilities issued by sectors/operators.

In order to clarify some of the issues related to the analysis of liquidity, a fundamental reference is Hicks (1967, 1974), who draws specific attention to the term structure of the interest rates as a key connecting factor between liquidity preference, monetary analysis and portfolio selection.

M0 (Base Money) is the sum of currency in circulation and banks’ reserves with the central bank. The same definition is given here for perfectly liquid assets (L0). M1 is the sum of currency plus banks’ demand deposits. Also this aggregate is highly liquid being redeemable in terms of base money at par on demand; the principal uncertainty relates to deposits held with banks which might be (become) illiquid or even insolvent. A bank produces perfect liquid asset if the nominal value of its corresponding liability is fully guaranteed (Mazzoni 2016). Liquidity is related to both the store of value and the transactions motives to hold money: in the extreme case of hyperinflation, these features would be lost (Hicks 1974).

In general, liquidity aggregates are a broader measure than broad money, but considerable overlaps exist between liquid and monetary assets. As indicated, this should not lead to confusing the two typologies, and more specifically to defining liquidity with reference to the key attribute of money: the payment for goods and services, the repayment of debt and the acquisition of assets. This approach is not uncommon and is apparently partially endorsed also by the ECB: “The notion of liquidity in the economic literature relates to the ability of an economic agent to exchange his or her existing wealth for goods and services or for other assets. In this definition, two issues should be noted. First, liquidity can be understood in terms of flows (as opposed to stocks), in other words, it is a flow concept. In our framework, liquidity will refer to the unhindered flows among the agents of the financial system, with a particular focus on the flows among the central bank, commercial banks and markets. Second, liquidity refers to the “ability” of realising these flows” (Nikolaou 2009).

The other principle concern with this line of analysis refers to the tenet that liquidity is a flow variable and should be examined strictly in terms of flow analysis. This approach is typically operational and should not be disregarded, but it is evidently incomplete. Liquidity and illiquidity processes are dynamic, stochastic and therefore linked to the passage of time. Measurement of liquidity often requires reference to ratios of both stocks to flows and flows to stocks. It is by no means a coincidence that a famous debate after the publication of the General Theory was precisely on stock vs. flow analysis of liquidity preference and loanable funds theories (Hicks 1939; Patinkin 1958). The interconnectedness should not however lead to fuzziness. Any economic/financial variable is characterised by unit of measurement (m) and time dimension (t): without a precise definition of both, analysis of economic phenomena and processes is necessarily blurred and ultimately unsatisfactory. The concept of liquidity is emblematic of these difficulties. Stock variables exist at a point in time, and flows are defined over a time interval. Capitalisation of flows permits to establish consistent relationships with stocks. The dimension of the reciprocal of the rate of interest with the selected appropriate maturity is the corresponding time interval. As originally explained by Hicks (1974), what is relevant in respect of (stock) liquidity is not “the” rate of interest (defined as the marginal rate of substitution between bonds and money), but the spread between short and long rates (the marginal rate of substitution between bonds and bills).

A key dimension of liquidity is its intrinsic stochastic nature (ECB 2002 and Watanabe 2003), beyond the L0 = M0 stock levels. It is only the value of perfectly liquid assets which is insensitive to the arrival of new information (Diamond and Dybvig 1983; Gorton 2010; de Angelo and Stulz 2013). The problem of statistical modelling of risk can be handled with relative ease in the traditional approach, where the assumptions are made of (i) exogenous/fundamental risk and (ii) Gaussian/stationary distributions. If instead, in the framework of Table 3, allowance is made for endogenous/systemic risk, stochastic volatility can become time-varying. More specifically, assets with uncorrelated statistical distributions under idiosyncratic risk predominance can become highly correlated. The notable exception, as indicated, is represented by central bank liabilities which retain their unique properties. Correlations, volatilities and asset/market/funding liquidities become path dependent and give rise to feedback loops, possible financial bubbles and liquidity spirals.Footnote 22

Table 3 Prototype overview of monetary, liquid, marketable assets and of asset portfolio selection

More generally the overall analysis should not be conducted exclusively in terms of individual idiosyncratic risks, but with reference to a holistic approach (Persaud 2016). As indicated in this paper, a complex interdependent system framework is required, which allows for fallacies of composition/division, micro- vs. macro-prudential perspectives, systematic interdependence of economic policies. This broader framework embraces the role and significance of L0 stock analysis and of liquidity creation/support of the central bank (flow approach), notably in its traditional fundamental function of LOLR (Thornton 1802; Bagehot 1873).Footnote 23 In the Banking Union framework, these key operations are not the direct responsibility of the ECB (Art. 14.4 of the ECB and ELA ECB decision of 18 October 2013) (Lamandini and Munoz 2015).Footnote 24 Instead, since 2012, the LOLR has been de facto applied by the ECB to the government bond market to break the bank sovereign debt-liquidity/solvency spiralsFootnote 25: this created however a new liquidity problem for Treasury bills, because of the drying up of the market for such securities.

Copyright information

© 2018 The Author(s)

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Masera, R. (2018). Political Economy of Liquidity: The European Economic and Monetary Union. In: Cardinale, I., Scazzieri, R. (eds) The Palgrave Handbook of Political Economy. Palgrave Macmillan, London. https://doi.org/10.1057/978-1-137-44254-3_14

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/978-1-137-44254-3_14

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Palgrave Macmillan, London

  • Print ISBN: 978-1-137-44253-6

  • Online ISBN: 978-1-137-44254-3

  • eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics