Skip to main content

Elementary Tools for Stochasitc Analysis

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Evolutionary Economics

Part of the book series: Springer Texts in Business and Economics ((STBE))

  • 32 Accesses

Abstract

Lambert Adolf Jacob Quételet (1796–1874), the astronomer, first attempted to ground statistical sociology with the ‘average man’ (l’ homme moyen). He then exhibits an interesting question about the difference between criminals and ordinary people. Even if the probability distribution of crime occurrence is Gaussian, different theoretical backgrounds arise depending on whether crime is regarded as acquired or innate. If

it is considered acquired, there will be a uniform population with a certain probability of becoming a criminal, whereas if all criminals are congenital, there is a probability of being born a criminal. Quételet is also currently well known by the body mass index (BMI) scale, originally called the Quetelet Index. The obesity index is also attributed to him. He proposed that society be modeled using mathematical probability and social statistics, which brought the ‘enthusiasm for normal distributions’ of natural and social scientists in the 19th century. Indeed, from the discoveries of Bernoulli and de Moivre, it came to be thought that large amounts of data on completely chance events could be used to argue for nonchance regularities. Moreover, the large amounts of data that came to be accumulated with the industrial revolution were also thought to apply to population, industry and society. This was the birth moment of social statistics. It came to be thought that distribution laws such as the Gaussian normal curve could be recognised everywhere. In other words, if we can consider ‘normal size’, we can also talk about ‘normal distribution’. Clearly, everyone has the freedom to be or not to be a criminal. However, the probability may be already determined at birth. In this circumstance, unlimited freedom and responsibility could not be guranteed. From the dawn of the Enlightenment, the ideals of freedom and probabilistic design have not always been compatible. The enthusiasm of probability distribution, on the contrary, was rather irrelevant to ethics. As time evolved since the enthusiasim due to Quételet, various problems were addressed, such as ‘the existence of dependence or interaction between individual data, or the occurrence of unusually large scatter and fluctuations’, and the assumption of normality in asset price fluctuations, for example in economic examples, was dismissed. This is nothing but an achievement of econophysics, but this is a very recent one. Finally, we learn the Polya urn process as a good reference mechanism to grasp the evolution of the system.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    A more sophisticated version of this is the auto-regressive integral moving average model, ARIMA(pqr). MA(1) is an approximate function of \(AR(\infty )\).

  2. 2.

    Also see Fama (1965).

  3. 3.

    The British physician and natural scientist Francis Galton (1822–1911), who first tried to measure intelligence, stressed the law of the large number: “I hardly know anything other than this whose imagination is influenced in such a way like the marvelous form of cosmic order, which is expressed by the law of the error frequency. It prevails with bright serenity, and complete self-denial in the middle of the wildest confusion. The greater the rabble, the greater the obvious anarchy. Its influence is surely the highest law of senselessness”.

  4. 4.

    See Mandelbrot (1963). Lévy distributions are also found in nature, e.g., in spectroscopy, with many cases seen in solar flare data. See Lévy (1925).

  5. 5.

    http://demonstrations.wolfram.com/GeneralizedCentralLimitTheorem/.

  6. 6.

    See Cook (2010).

  7. 7.

    See Appendix in Aruka (2015): “An elementary derivation of the one-dimensional central limit theorem from the random walk”.

  8. 8.

    o(1) represents a function tending to 0.

  9. 9.

    http://mathworld.wolfram.com/ParetoDistribution.html.

  10. 10.

    See Nolan (2005, 2020).

  11. 11.

    The power law differs from the power distribution The probability density for values in a power distribution is proportional to \(x^{a-1}\) for \(0 < x \le 1/k\) and zero otherwise.

  12. 12.

    A linear combination of independent identically distributed stable random variables is also stable.

  13. 13.

    As already noted, the generalized CLT still holds.

  14. 14.

    DFR indicates that the ability to make more money might increase with one’s income (Singh & Maddala, 2008, 28).

  15. 15.

    c is eliminated. If \(x = 0\), \(F(0) = 0\). It follows that \(c = b^{1/a}\).

  16. 16.

    It is clear that \(F\rightarrow 1 \text{ as }\, x\rightarrow \infty \).

  17. 17.

    See Champernowne (1953) and Fisk (1961).

  18. 18.

    See Pitman (1995), Yamato and Sibuya (2000), and Yamato and Sibuya (2003).

References

  • Aoki, M., & Yoshikawa, H. (2006). Reconstructing macroeconomics: A perspective from statistical physics and combinatorial stochastic processes (p. 333). Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Arthur, W. B. (1994). Increasing returns and path dependence in the economy, Japanese ed. University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aruka, Y. (2015). Hodgson’s bibliometric report and the reconstruction plan of economics. Evolutionary and Institutional Economics Review, 15(1), 189–202.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barabási, A. L., & Albert, A. L. (1999). Emergence of scaling in random networks. Science, 286(5439), 509–512. October.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Champernowne, D. G. (1953). A model of income distribution. Economic Journal, 63(2), 318–351.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cook, J. D. (2010). Central limit theorems. Wolfram Demonstrations. http://www.johndcook.com/central_limit_theorems.html linked from Cook (2010): How the central limit theorem began? http://www.johndcook.com/blog/2010/01/05/how-the-central-limit-theorem-began/

  • Ewens, W. J. (1972). The sampling theory of selectivity neutral Allels. Theoretical Population Biology, 3, 87–112.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fama, E. (1965). The behavior of stock market prices. Journal of Business, 38, 34–105. https://doi.org/10.1086/294743.

  • Fama, E. (1970). Efficient capital markets: A review of theory and empirical work. Journal of Finance, 25(2), 383–417. https://doi.org/10.2307/2325486.JSTOR2325486.

  • Fisk, P. R. (1961). The graduation of income distributions. Econometrica, 20(4), 171–185.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johnson, N. F., Jefferies, P., & Hui, P. M. (2003). Financial market complexity: What physics can tell us about market behaviour. Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Lévy, P. (1925/2016). Calcul des probabilités. Gauthier-Villars, Cambridge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mainzer, K. (2007). Kapitel 7: Zufall in Kultur, Wirtschaft, und Gesselschaft. In Der kreative Zufall: Wie das Neue in die Welt kommt? CH Beck.

    Google Scholar 

  • Manderbrot, B. (1963). The variation of certain speculative prices. Journal of Business, 36(4), 394–419.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Manderbrot, B. (2001). Scaling in financial prices. Quantitative Finance, 1(6), 641–649.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mantegna, R. H., & Stanley, H. E. (2001). An introduction to econophysics: Correlations and complexity in finance.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nolan, J. P. (2020). Univariate stable distributions: Models for heavy tailed data.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nolan, J. P. (2005). Stable distributions: Models for heavy tailed data. Birkhäuser.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ohkubo, J., Yasuda, M., & Tanaka, K. (2005). Preferential urn model and nongrowing complex networks. Physical Review E, 72(065104), 1–4. December.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ohkubo, J., Yasuda, M., & Tanaka, K. (2006). Replica analysis of preferential urn mode; erratum, 76(4), 1, article no. 048001; (2007, April). Journal of the Physical Society of Japan, 75(074802), 1–6.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pitman, J. (1995). Exchangeable and partially exchangeable random partitions. Probability Theory and Related Fields, 102, 145–158. November.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Singh, S. K., & Maddala, G. S. (2008). A function for size distribution of income. In D. Chotikapanich (Ed.), Modeling income distributions and Lorenz curves (Chapter 2:24–32). Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Swell, M. (2011). Characterization of financial time series.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yamato, H., & Sibuya, M. (2000). Moments of some statistics of pitman sampling formula. Bulletin of Informatics and Cybernetics, 32(1), 1–10.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yamato, H., & Sibuya, M. (2003). Pitman sampling formula and related topics (in Japanese). Proceedings of the Institute of Statistical Mathematics, 51(2), 351–372.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Yuji Aruka .

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2024 The Editor(s) (if applicable) and The Author(s), under exclusive license to Springer Nature Singapore Pte Ltd.

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Aruka, Y. (2024). Elementary Tools for Stochasitc Analysis. In: Evolutionary Economics. Springer Texts in Business and Economics. Springer, Singapore. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-97-1382-0_12

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics