Skip to main content

Part of the book series: SpringerBriefs in Economics ((BRIEFSECONOMICS))

  • 20 Accesses

Abstract

This chapter provides overview of the book. Considering the evolution of global value chains (GVCs), this book’s objectives are as follows: (1) GVC participation and influencing factors: To elucidate the methodologies used to analyze GVC participation and examine the factors influencing the participation of developing nations, especially the link between GVC participation and income levels. (2) GVC upgrading and influencing factors: To understand the methodologies for analyzing GVC upgrading and explore the elements affecting GVC enhancement in developing nations. This is particularly relevant for nations experiencing a surge in imported inputs due to weak industry supplier bases. (3) The role of connectivity in GVC dynamics: To delve into the evolution and present state of maritime and aviation connectivity and examine its repercussions on GVC involvement and the subsequent transformation of industrial frameworks.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

eBook
USD 16.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 16.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    This process, which started in the early nineteenth century, is called globalization’s “first unbundling,” because production and consumption were separated and vertical trade commenced between the North and South.

  2. 2.

    Krugman and Venables (1995) made a similar argument. Their spatial economics model focuses on the decline in transport costs as a driving force for the agglomeration of manufacturing activities in the North and its subsequent dispersion to the South. Baldwin’s novelty, however, lies in the introduction of coordination costs, closely associated with information and communication costs.

  3. 3.

    GVCs have been studied by a variety of researchers, including not only economists but also sociologists, economic geographers, and business strategists. Their studies examine the globalized economy from different angles. Economists typically delve into the dynamics of production processes through the lens of the fragmentation theory. However, other researchers predominantly examine GVCs from the perspective of business activities, focusing on the value chain concept, which dissects the sequential series of interdependent activities integral to the creation, production, and delivery of a product or service. This encompasses everything from initial conception, various production stages, delivery to end consumers, and post-sale services to the eventual disposal or recycling (Porter 1985). Theoretical frameworks that are relevant to the value chain concept include global commodity chains (GCCs: Gereffi 1994), global value chains (GVCs: Gereffi et al. 2005), and global production networks (GPNs: Henderson et al. 2002). In contrast, the fragmentation theory focuses on a specific facet of value chains: geographical distribution of parts and component manufacturing within comprehensive, vertically integrated production processes. The modern multi-country input-output methodology broadens the analytical spectrum to encapsulate the value chain concept. However, there are inherent limitations with input-output data. These include the absence of granular data, especially in service sectors, categorization based on industry—rather than business functions, and transactions recorded domestically rather than by nationality (Sturgeon et al. 2013; Inomata 2017).

  4. 4.

    Production blocks are connected via service links, i.e., the bundle of activities comprising transportation, insurance, telecommunication, quality control, and management coordination to ensure the production blocks interact suitably (Arndt and Kierzkowski 2001). In this context, Yi (2003, 2010) emphasized the impact of trade cost on production fragmentation because of two magnification forces: (1) goods that cross national borders multiple times incur tariffs and transportation costs multiple times; (2) tariffs are applied to gross imports, even though the value added by the direct exporter may be only a fraction of this amount.

  5. 5.

    In addition to the onshoring or offshoring decision, firms must make an important determination, namely, to “integrate or outsource.” The firm’s choice of the organizational form was studied by Antràs and Helpman (2004), who argued that firm heterogeneity in terms of productivity affects this decision. The most productive firm would choose to undertake foreign direct investment, the next most productive firm would choose offshore outsourcing, and firms that cannot undertake offshore outsourcing would choose either domestic production or domestic outsourcing. For a comprehensive review of economic theories related to GVCs, see Inomata (2017).

  6. 6.

    For details on the middle-income trap, see Chap. 5.

  7. 7.

    As an important exception, Limão and Venables (2001) used actual shipping company quotes for the cost of transporting a standard container from Baltimore in the US to selected destinations to estimate the difference in transportation costs by transport modes; this was used to construct a dataset for various countries. However, this approach leaves a question regarding the representativeness of the sample routes. Limão and Venables (2001) also used the ratio of CIF (cost, insurance, and freight) to FOB (free on board) values of bilateral trade as a proxy for trade costs. Again, however, there are some problems in the quality and availability of data.

References

  • Anderson JE (2010) The gravity model. Ann Rev Econ 3(1):133–160

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Antràs P, Helpman E (2004) Global sourcing. J Polit Econ 112(3):552–580

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arndt SW, Kierzkowski H (2001) Introduction. In: Fragmentation: new production patterns in the world economy. Oxford: Oxford University Press

    Google Scholar 

  • Baldwin R (2011) Trade and Industrialization after Globalization’s 2nd unbundling: how building and joining a supply chain are different and why it matters. NBER Working Paper 17716

    Google Scholar 

  • Baldwin R (2016) The great convergence: information technology and the new globalization. Cambridge MA: The Belknap Press of Harvard University Press

    Google Scholar 

  • Gereffi G (1994) The organization of buyer-driven global commodity chains: how U.S. retailers shape overseas production networks. In: Gereffi G, Korzeniewicz M (eds) Commodity chains and global capitalism. Westport: Praeger: 95–122

    Google Scholar 

  • Gereffi G, Humphrey J, Sturgeon T (2005) The governance of global value chains. Rev Int Political Econ 12(1):78–104

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henderson J, Dicken P, Hess M, Coe NM, Yeung H (2002) Global production networks and the analysis of economic development. Rev Int Political Econ 9(3):436–464

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Inomata S (2017) Analytical frameworks for global value chains: an overview. In: Global value chain development report 2017, Washington, DC: The World Bank Group

    Google Scholar 

  • Jones RW, Kierzkowski H (1990) The role of services in production and international trade: a theoretical framework. In: The political economy of international trade: essays in Honor of Robert E. Baldwin edited by Ronald W. Jones and Ann Kruger. Oxford: Basil Blackwell

    Google Scholar 

  • Kabir M, Salim R, Al-Mawali N (2017) The gravity model and trade flows: recent developments in econometric modeling and empirical evidence. Econ Anal Policy, 56:60–71

    Google Scholar 

  • Kawakami M, Goto K (2021) Factory asia: global value chains and local firm development. In: Goto K, Endo T, Ito A (eds) The asian economy: contemporary issues and challenges. London: Routledge

    Google Scholar 

  • Krugman P, Venables A (1995) Globalization and inequality of nations. Quart J Econ 110:857–880

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lall S (2003) Reviving industrial strategy: the role of government policy in building industrial competitiveness. G-24 Discussion Paper 28

    Google Scholar 

  • Lall S, Albaladejo M, Zhang J (2004) Mapping fragmentation: electronics and automobiles in Southeast Asia and Latin America. Oxf Dev Stud 32(3):407–432

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li X, Meng B, Wang Z (2019) Recent patterns of global production and GVC participation. In: Global value chain development report 2019: technological innovation, supply chain trade, and workers in a globalized world. Geneve: World Trade Organization

    Google Scholar 

  • Mayer T, Zignago S (2011) Notes on CEPII’s distances measures: the GeoDist database. CEPII Working Paper 2011- 25, December 2011, CEPII

    Google Scholar 

  • Porter ME (1985) Competitive advantage: creating and sustaining superior performance. The Free Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Sturgeon T, Nielsen P, Linden G, Gereffi G, Brown C (2013) Direct measurement of global value chains: collecting product- and firm- level statistics on value added and business function outsourcing and offshoring. In: Mattoo A, Wang Z, Wei S-J (eds) Trade in Value Added: Developing New Measures of Cross-Border Trade. World Bank, Washington DC, pp 289–320

    Google Scholar 

  • WTO (2022) Regional Trade Agreements Database (https://rtais.wto.org/UI/PublicMaintainRTAHome.aspx accessed on November 20, 2022)

  • WTO (2023) Trade Cost Index (http://tradecosts.wto.org/. Accessed May 7, 2023)

  • World Bank (2023) World Development Indicators (https://databank.worldbank.org/source/world-development-indicators. Accessed May 7, 2023)

  • Yi K-M (2003) Can vertical specialization explain the growth of world trade? J Polit Econ 111:52–102

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yi K-M (2010) Can multi-stage production explain the home bias in trade? Amer Econ Rev 100(1):364–393

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Ikuo Kuroiwa .

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2024 Institute of Developing Economies, Japan External Trade Organization (IDE-JETRO)

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Kuroiwa, I., Umezaki, S. (2024). Introduction. In: Global Value Chains and Industrial Development. SpringerBriefs in Economics. Springer, Singapore. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-97-0021-9_1

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics