Skip to main content

Value Theory, Joint Production, and International Trade Issues

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Spectral Theory of Value and Actual Economies

Abstract

The application of the principles of the Sraffian theory to joint production or/and open economies further reveals the inner limits of the traditional value theory: it is found that many statements make no sense or are not verified. If, however, we are willing to consider produced means of production, positive profits, non-“golden rule” steady states, heterogeneous labour (primary inputs), and joint-products as “market failures”, as well as joint production through the lens of single production, then we are not required to move away from the classical–Marxian–neoclassical one-commodity world. In the opposite case, a specific analysis of each particular issue must be made, and the general conclusion is that open, joint-product economies should be treated as the norm, whereas closed, single-product economies and their special properties should be pointed out as limiting paradigms.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 99.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 129.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 129.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    The relaxation of these two assumptions regarding consumption demand is not absolutely necessary for our present purposes (thus, it is left to the reader; also see Chap. 2, footnote 23).

  2. 2.

    As Salvadori and Steedman (1988a) remark, “Sraffa’s phrase “requirements for use” is not a standard term in economic analysis and Sraffa provides no explication of this phrase. Thus one is obliged to be cautious in offering an interpretation. Nevertheless it might seem that Sraffa was seeking to de-emphasize the subjective elements in the determination of the pattern of output, without denying them” (p. 168, footnote 2).

  3. 3.

    It is often overlooked that Sraffa’s (1960) three chapters on “Joint Production” do not provide a general treatment of this issue but “are in the main a preliminary to the discussion of Fixed Capital and Land in Chaps. X and XI” (p. 43, footnote 1). For general treatments, see Bidard (1991, Part 2; 1997), Kurz and Salvadori (1995, Chaps. 7, 8, and 9) and the references (and historical notes) therein. Finally, for critical remarks and broader discussions on the “golden rule hypothesis”, see Latham (1975), Goodwin (1972), Nuti (1970).

  4. 4.

    For an analytical investigation of the 2 × 2 case, see Abraham-Frois and Berrebi (1984).

  5. 5.

    These examples have been built by correcting and modifying, respectively, two numerical examples provided by Bidard (1997, pp. 689–690) and further examined by Mariolis (2004a, 2010, Essay 2; 2019) and Mariolis and Soklis (2018). For other specific features of the joint production economies, see Chaps. 5, 6, 7, 8, and 9 of this book.

  6. 6.

    The non-monotonic w − r curves analysed by, for instance, Filippini and Filippini (1984, pp. 57–62) have no specific economic content and are, therefore, unreal: the authors, on the one hand, do not take into account the requirements for use, and, on the other hand, assume that all the available processes operate. That is to say, those curves are algebraic w − r curves.

  7. 7.

    For r > 0.1, we obtain

    $$ {v}_11.05+{v}_20.95=1 $$

    and, therefore, “labour values” are not uniquely determined.

  8. 8.

    In 2 × 2 economies, \( \ddot{w}\ne 0 \); hence, Eqs. (4.14) and (4.15) imply that a necessary condition for a non-monotonic w − r curve is that the eigenvalues of H are complex. Thus, it is not unexpected that the 2 × 2, no w − r trade-off, numerical example analysed by d’Autume (1988, pp. 343–344) has the same production structure as the present example. According to d’Autume (1986, 1988), when we adopt the viewpoint of the “general equilibrium theory”, the only real paradox, specific to the joint production case, is the possibility that, outside the “golden rule” path, the w − r curve is non-monotonic.

  9. 9.

    See Chaps. 3 and 5 of the present book.

  10. 10.

    It may be noted that, in our numerical example, p1/p2 is a linear function of the profit rate (defined by Eq. (4.10)), and the mean of the relative error between the actual w − r curve (defined by Eq. (4.11)) and its Taylor linear approximation about r = 0, i.e. w ≈ 1 − 7.25r, is almost 1.85%.

  11. 11.

    Such a sign change of \( \ddot{w} \) is impossible in the corresponding single production case (i.e. two commodities and one production technique).

  12. 12.

    Compare with Debreu (1984, p. 50). According to Kehoe (1985), the only economically interpretable restrictions that imply uniqueness of equilibrium in models of economic competition are either that the demand side behaves like a single consumer or that the supply side satisfies the “non-substitution theorem”; also see Mas-Colell (1985, Chap. 6).

  13. 13.

    For the bases of the Ricardian, neoclassical, and Sraffian theories of open economies, as well as for their negative and positive relationships, see Baldone (2000), Giammanco (1998), Mainwaring (1974a), Parrinello (1970), Ravix (1979, 1990), Sraffa (1930), Steedman (1979a, Chaps. 1 and 2; 1979b, Essay 1; 1999), Steedman and Metcalfe (1973a, 1973b, 1981). For a comprehensive von Neumann analysis of the “small”, growing open economy case (i.e. a growing economy facing given world prices and a world economy growing at least as fast as the economy under consideration), see Steedman (1979c).

  14. 14.

    On Mihail Manoilescu’s and Dimosthenis Stefanidis’s contributions, see Hagen (1958) and Mariolis (2018), respectively. For the neoclassical theory of “domestic distortions” and “infant-economy protection”, see, e.g. Chacholiades (1978, Chaps. 20 and 21).

  15. 15.

    For a more recent, non-Sraffian exchange on the topic, see Jones (1992) and Samuelson (1992), while Jones (2012) notes: “In early discussions of activity analysis […] activities allowed joint production (i.e., production processes involving not only multiple inputs, but also multiple outputs). […] In trade theory the lack of joint production insures an asymmetry between inputs (many) and outputs (one) that is the basis for the Stolper–Samuelson theorem (1941). As to its effect on the factor-price equalization theorem, opinions differ. For example, see Samuelson (1992) and Jones (1992)” (p. 151, footnote 2).

  16. 16.

    In single production economies also, it is entirely possible for international equilibrium price ratios to exist, which do not lie between the corresponding autarky price ratios (Steedman 1979a, pp. 115–116). However, this presupposes that more than two commodities are produced.

  17. 17.

    For further on the “gains from free trade”, i.e. “specialization gain” and “transition (from autarky to free trade) gain”, the possibility of negative “overall gain from free trade” and the consequent implications for the theories of “economic integration” and economic policy, see Mainwaring (1976a, 1979, 1991, Chap. 2), Mariolis (2000, 2005a, 2005b), Montani (2010, 2012), Steedman (1979a, 1979b, 2018).

  18. 18.

    Compare with Fig. 2 in Mainwaring (1974b, p. 541).

  19. 19.

    See point Δ in Fig. 4.7. At point Γ it holds that D = 0.

  20. 20.

    We recall, therefore, Ricardo’s (1817) view, “[T]he rate of profits can never be increased but by a fall in wages, and that there can be no permanent fall of wages but in consequence of a fall of the necessaries on which wages are expended. If, therefore, by the extension of foreign trade, or by improvements in machinery, the food and necessaries of the labourer can be brought to market at a reduced price, profits will rise.” (p. 132).

  21. 21.

    Such a sign change of {C, D} is impossible in the corresponding single production case.

  22. 22.

    There are also cases of non-validity of this law, which are attributed to features of consumption demand only (see, e.g. Chacholiades 1978, pp. 149–151).

  23. 23.

    Also see Metcalfe and Steedman (1981) and Montet (1979). Nevertheless, there are H–O–S type theorems which fail to hold even when r = g = 0 and there are at least two primary inputs and only one produced input (Steedman 2005; Opocher and Steedman 2015, Chap. 2).

  24. 24.

    Or, according to Samuelson (1994), “Ricardo–Viner–Harrod–Balassa–Samuelson–Penn–Bhagwati effect”.

  25. 25.

    What follows draws on Mariolis (2008), Mariolis et al. (2015).

  26. 26.

    Z = 1 iff A is strictly triangular and, therefore, nilpotent (as in the Austrian-type models).

  27. 27.

    For simplicity, the reader may consider the fixed input coefficients case.

  28. 28.

    The two-sector case is often used for the analysis of real phenomena (such as inflation differentials across Eurozone economies).

  29. 29.

    On the invalidity of these two theorems, also see Mainwaring (1976b, 1978), Steedman (1979b, Essays 5), Steedman and Metcalfe (1973b). Nevertheless, the prices of the non-Sraffian Standard commodities (see Sects. 3.2.1 and 10.4 of the present book), in terms of the Sraffian Standard commodity, are strictly decreasing functions of the profit rate and, therefore, in accordance with these two theorems (Mariolis 2004b; Mariolis and Tsoulfidis 2011, pp. 93–96).

  30. 30.

    The relaxation of the assumption regarding “small” economies complicates the analysis (without substantially changing its basic conclusion), because it implies that π3/π2 is determined in terms of international relative supply and demand.

  31. 31.

    Their model is a two-sector model. The existence of a second tradable commodity necessitates the introduction of additional assumptions.

  32. 32.

    Traditionally, it is argued that, “Empirically, nontraded goods tend to be at least as labour-intensive as traded goods, so the condition θL1 ≥ (θL2, θL3) [using our symbols] holds in practice. Furthermore, productivity growth in nontradables historically has been lower than in tradables. One reason for relatively low productivity growth in the nontradables sector is its substantial overlap with services, which are inherently less susceptible to standardization and mechanization than are manufactures or agriculture” (Obstfeld and Rogoff 1998, p. 209; emphasis added. Also see the relevant Special Issue of the Review of International Economics 1994). However, these observations are highly disputable: consider what was said on the basis of Eq. (4.34), as well as the fact that the empirically relevant case of joint production creates a new kind of insurmountable problems for the traditional approaches. For instance, in that case, (i) the definition of a commodity as “relatively labour-intensive” makes no sense; (ii) relative prices depend on the demand conditions; and (iii) productivity growth does not necessarily lead to an increase in the real wage rate.

  33. 33.

    It should be noted that θL2 = θL3 implies that

    $$ \overset{\frown }{w}={\overset{\frown }{\tau}}_1{\theta}_{L1}^{-1}={\overset{\frown }{\tau}}_2{\theta}_{L2}^{-1}={\overset{\frown }{w}}^{\ast },\kern0.5 em \overset{\frown }{\mathrm{I}}={\overset{\frown }{\mathrm{I}}}^{\ast }=0 $$

    while θ12 = θ13 implies that θL2 = θL3.

  34. 34.

    Both Balassa (1964, pp. 585–586) and Samuelson (1964, pp. 147–148) refer to the non-tradable commodities as services. Thus, in the relevant literature it is considered that Eq. (4.42) are in accordance with this reference. Of course, all these are simplifications (also see Steedman 1979a, pp. 99–105).

  35. 35.

    The hitherto available empirical evidence on the relative price effects of total productivity shift (see Eq. (4.34)), with \( {\overset{\frown }{\boldsymbol{\uptau}}}^{\mathrm{T}}=\overset{\frown }{\tau }{\mathbf{e}}^{\mathrm{T}} \)) suggests that the direction of the price movements is, more often than not, governed by the labour cost condition, while this is reduced to the “skew distribution” (see Chap. 3 of this book) of the eigenvalues of the matrices, ΘK, of the relative shares of the capital commodities (Mariolis et al. 2015). The empirical evidence on the H–B–S effect provides rather mixed findings, while, for instance, according to Tica and Družić (2006), “[t]he growing body of evidence makes it difficult to ignore the HBS theory and definitely points towards professional rethinking about the contemporary significance of the Harrod–Balassa–Samuelson theory.” (p. 15).

References

  • Abraham-Frois, G., & Berrebi, E. (1984). Taux de profit minimum dans les modèles de production. In C. Bidard (Ed.), La production jointe. Nouveaux débats (pp. 211–229). Paris: Economica.

    Google Scholar 

  • Balassa, B. (1964). The purchasing-power parity doctrine: A reappraisal. Journal of Political Economy, 72(6), 584–596.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baldone, S. (2000). A comment on Steedman. In T. Cozzi & R. Marchionatti (Eds.), Piero Sraffa’s political economy: A centenary estimate (pp. 359–361). London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bhagwati, J. N. (1984). Why are services cheaper in the poor countries? The Economic Journal, 94(374), 279–286.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bidard, C. (1991). Prix, reproduction, rareté. Paris: Dunod.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bidard, C. (1996). All-engaging systems. Economic Systems Research, 8(4), 323–340.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bidard, C. (1997). Pure joint production. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 21(6), 685–701.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brewer, A. (1985). Trade with fixed real wages and mobile capital. Journal of International Economics, 18(1–2), 177–186.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Burmeister, E., & Dobell, R. A. (1970). Mathematical theories of economic growth. New York: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Burmeister, E., & Kuga, K. (1970). The factor-price frontier, duality and joint production. The Review of Economic Studies, 37(1), 11–19.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chacholiades, M. (1978). International trade theory and policy. Singapore: McGraw-Hill.

    Google Scholar 

  • d’Autume, A. (1986). Le rôle intime de la demande dans la production jointe. In R. Arena & J.-L. Ravix (Eds.). (1990). Sraffa, trente ans après (pp. 245–256). Paris: Presses Universitaires de France.

    Google Scholar 

  • d’Autume, A. (1988). La production jointe: Le point de vue de la théorie de l’équilibre général. Revue Économique, 39(2), 325–347.

    Google Scholar 

  • Debreu, G. (1984). Théorie de la valeur. Analyse axiomatique de l’équilibre économique. Suivi d’un inédit en français: Existence d’un équilibre concurrentiel (2e éd.). Paris: Dunod.

    Google Scholar 

  • Diewert, W. E. (1971). An application of the Shephard duality theorem: A generalized Leontief production function. Journal of Political Economy, 79(3), 481–507.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dmitriev, V. K. (1974). Economic essays on value, competition and utility. Edited with an introduction by D. M. Nuti. London: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Emmanuel, A. (1969). L’échange inégal: essai sur les antagonismes dans les rapports économiques internationaux. Paris: François Maspero.

    Google Scholar 

  • Emmanuel, A. (1975). Unequal exchange revisited. Discussion Paper No. 77, Institute of Development Studies, University of Sussex.

    Google Scholar 

  • Filippini, C., & Filippini, L. (1982). Two theorems on joint production. The Economic Journal, 92(366), 386–390.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Filippini, C., & Filippini, L. (1984). La frontière de prix des facteurs dans les modèles de production jointe. In C. Bidard (Ed.), La production jointe. Nouveaux débats (pp. 52–64). Paris: Economica.

    Google Scholar 

  • Giammanco, M. D. (1998). Scarcity of resources in a Sraffian framework of international trade. Metroeconomica, 49(3), 300–318.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goodwin, R. M. (1972). Capitalism’s golden rule. Bulletin of the Conference of Socialist Economist, 2(2), 56. Reprinted in R. M. Goodwin (1982). Essays in Economic Dynamics (pp. 171–172). London: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hagen, E. E. (1958). An economic justification of protectionism. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 72(4), 496–514.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harrod, R. F. (1933). International economics. London: James Nisbet and Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hilferding, R. (1981). Finance capital. A study of the latest phase of capitalist development. Edited with an introduction by T. Bottomore from translations by M. Watnick and S. Gordon. London: Routledge & Kegan Paul.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holley, J. L. (1951). Note on the inversion of the Leontief Matrix. Econometrica, 19(3), 317–320.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jones, R. W. (1992). Jointness in production and factor-price equalization. Review of International Economics, 1(1), 10–18.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jones, R. W. (2012). General equilibrium theory and competitive trade models. International Journal of Economic Theory, 8(2), 149–164.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jones, R. W., & Weder, R. (Eds.). (2017). 200 Years of Ricardian trade theory. Challenges of globalization. Cham: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kahn, R. F. (1931). The relation of home investment to unemployment. The Economic Journal, 41(162), 173–198.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kehoe, T. J. (1985). Multiplicity of equilibria and comparative statics. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 100(1), 119–147.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kravis I. B., & Lipsey R. E. (1983). Towards an explanation of national price levels. Princeton Studies in International Financial, no. 52. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kravis, I. B., & Lipsey, R. E. (1988). National price levels and the prices of tradables and nontradables. The American Economic Review. Papers and Proceedings of the One-Hundredth Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association, 78(2), 474–478.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kurz, H. D., & Salvadori, N. (1995). Theory of production. A long-period analysis. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Latham, R. W. (1975). The golden rule of accumulation under alternative savings assumptions. Oxford Economic Papers, 27(3), 462–469.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lenin, V. I. (1917). Imperialism, the highest stage of capitalism. A popular outline. In V. I. Lenin (Ed.), Collected works (Vol. 22, pp. 185–304). Moscow: Progress Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mainwaring, L. (1974a). A neo-Ricardian analysis of trade. Ph.D. Thesis, Manchester: University of Manchester.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mainwaring, L. (1974b). A neo-Ricardian analysis of international trade. Kyklos, 27(3), 537–553. Reprinted in I. Steedman (Ed.). (1979). Fundamental issues in trade theory (pp. 110–122). London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mainwaring, L. (1976a). The correction of neo-Ricardian trade losses. Economia Internazionale/International Economics, 29(1), 92–99.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mainwaring, L. (1976b). Relative prices and “factor price” equalisation in a heterogeneous capital goods model. Australian Economic Papers, 15(26), 109–118. Reprinted in I. Steedman (Ed.). (1979). Fundamental issues in trade theory (pp. 77–89). London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mainwaring, L. (1978). The interest rate equalisation theorem with non-traded goods. Journal of International Economics, 8(1), 11–19. Reprinted in I. Steedman (Ed.), (1979). Fundamental issues in trade theory (pp. 90–98). London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mainwaring, L. (1979). On the transition from autarky to trade. In I. Steedman (Ed.). (1979). Fundamental issues in trade theory (pp. 131–141). London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mainwaring, L. (1991). Dynamics of uneven development. Aldershot: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Manoilescu, M. (1929). Théorie du protectionism et de l’échange international. Paris: M. Giard.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mariolis, T. (2000). The division of labour in European Monetary Union: Absolute versus comparative advantage. European Research Studies, 3(1–2), 79–90.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mariolis, T. (2004a). Pure joint production and international trade: A note. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 28(3), 449–456.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mariolis, T. (2004b). A Sraffian approach to the Stolper–Samuelson theorem. Asian African Journal of Economics and Econometrics, 4(1), 1–11.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mariolis, T. (2005a). A neo-Ricardian critique of the traditional static theory of trade, customs unions and common markets. MPRA Paper No. 23088. Retrieved May 12, 2020, from https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/23088/.

  • Mariolis, T. (2005b). Endogenous growth and ambiguous steady-state gains from free trade. Indian Development Review. An International Journal of Development Economics, 3(1), 15–27.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mariolis, T. (2008). Heterogeneous capital goods and the Harrod–Balassa–Samuelson effect. Metroeconomica, 59(2), 238–248.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mariolis, T. (2010). Essays on the logical history of political economy. Athens: Matura (in Greek).

    Google Scholar 

  • Mariolis, T. (2018). Dimosthenis S. Stefanidis: The Greek pioneer of the theory of “unequal exchange” and cumulative causation in international economics. In T. Mariolis (Ed.), Essays on the work of Dimitris Batsis: “The heavy industry in Greece” (pp. 157–168). Athens: Tziola Publications (in Greek).

    Google Scholar 

  • Mariolis, T. (2019). The “second wave” of the Sraffian critical transcendence of the traditional political economy. Paper presented at the 1st Conference of the Study Group on Sraffian Economics: “From the Capital Theory Controversy in the 1960s to Greece’s Virtual Bankruptcy in 2010”, 11–12 April 2019, Panteion University, Athens, Greece (in Greek).

    Google Scholar 

  • Mariolis, T., & Soklis, G. (2018). The non-monotonic wage–profit curve and its implications for the traditional political economy. Paper presented at the 20th Conference of the Greek Historians of Economic Thought, 1–2 June 2018, University of Thessalia, Volos, Greece (in Greek).

    Google Scholar 

  • Mariolis, T., & Tsoulfidis, L. (2011). Eigenvalue distribution and the production price–profit rate relationship: Theory and empirical evidence. Evolutionary and Institutional Economics Review, 8(1), 87–122.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mariolis, T., Rodousakis, N., & Christodoulaki, A. (2015). Input–output evidence on the relative price effects of total productivity shift. International Review of Applied Economics, 29(2), 150–163.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marx, K. (1991). Capital. A critique of political economy. Volume Three. Harmondsworth: Penguin Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mas-Colell, A. (1985). The theory of general economic equilibrium. A differentiable approach. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Metcalfe, J. S., & Steedman, I. (1974). A note on the gain from trade. Economic Record, 50(4), 581–595. Reprinted in I. Steedman (Ed.). (1979). Fundamental issues in trade theory (pp. 47–63). London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Metcalfe, J. S., & Steedman, I. (1981). On two production possibility frontiers. Metroeconomica, 33(1-2-3), 1–19.

    Google Scholar 

  • Montani, G. (2010). The Neoricardian theory of economic integration. Bulletin of Political Economy, 4(1), 31–43.

    Google Scholar 

  • Montani, G. (2012). World trade and world money: A Neoricardian outlook on global economy. Bulletin of Political Economy, 6(1), 1–17.

    Google Scholar 

  • Montet, C. (1979). Reswitching and primary input use: A comment. The Economic Journal, 89(355), 642–647.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nuti, D. M. (1970). Capitalism, socialism and steady growth. The Economic Journal, 80(317), 32–57.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Obstfeld, M., & Rogoff, K. (1998). Foundations of international macroeconomics. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Opocher, A., & Steedman, I. (2015). Full industry equilibrium. A theory of the industrial long run. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Parrinello, S. (1970). Introduzione ad una teoria neoricardiana del commercio internazionale. Studi Economici, 25(3–4), 267–321.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ravix, J. T. (1979). Note sur la théorie ricardienne du commerce international. Cahiers d’économie politique/Papers in Political Economy, 5, 101–117.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ravix, J. T. (1990). Prix internationaux et spécialisation dans les analyses post-sraffaiennes du commerce international. In R. Arena & J.-L. Ravix (Eds.), Sraffa, trente ans après (pp. 413–425). Paris: Presses Universitaires de France.

    Google Scholar 

  • Review of International Economics. (1994). Special issue: Thirty years of the Balassa–Samuelson model. Review of International Economics, 2(3).

    Google Scholar 

  • Ricardo, D. (1817). On the principles of political economy and taxation. In D. Ricardo (1951–1973). The works and correspondence of David Ricardo (Vol. 1). Edited by P. Sraffa with the collaboration of M. H. Dobb. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rodrik, D. (2011). The globalization paradox. Why global markets, states, and democracy can’t coexist. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Salvadori, N., & Steedman, I. (1988a). Joint production analysis in a Sraffian framework. Bulletin of Economic Research, 40(3), 165–195.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Salvadori, N., & Steedman, I. (1988b). A note about the interest rate and the revenue function. Eastern Economic Journal, 14(2), 153–156.

    Google Scholar 

  • Salvadori, N., & Steedman, I. (1988c). No reswitching? No switching! Cambridge Journal of Economics, 12(4), 481–486.

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P. A. (1948). International trade and the equalisation of factor prices. The Economic Journal, 58(230), 163–184.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P. A. (1962). Parable and realism in capital theory: The surrogate production function. The Review of Economic Studies, 29(3), 193–206.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P. A. (1964). Theoretical notes on trade problems. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 46(2), 145–154.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P. A. (1992). Factor-price equalization by trade in joint and non-joint production. Review of International Economics, 1(1), 1–9.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P. A. (1994). Facets of Balassa-Samuelson thirty years later. Review of International Economics, 2(3), Special issue: Thirty years of the Balassa–Samuelson model, 201–226.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scarf, H. E., & Wilson, C. A. (2005). Uniqueness of equilibrium in the multicountry Ricardo model. In T. J. Kehoe, T. N. Srinivasan, & J. Whalley (Eds.), Frontiers in applied general equilibrium modeling. In honor of Herbert Scarf (pp. 24–44). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schefold, B. (1978). Multiple product techniques with properties of single product systems. Journal of Economics, 38(1–2), 29–53.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shephard, R. W. (1953). Cost and production functions. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Simpson, D. (1975). General equilibrium analysis. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sraffa, P. (1930). An alleged correction of Ricardo. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 44(3), 539–544.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sraffa, P. (1960). Production of commodities by means of commodities. Prelude to a critique of economic theory. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Steedman, I. (1975). Positive profits with negative surplus value. The Economic Journal, 85(337), 114–123.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Steedman, I. (1976a). Positive profits with negative surplus value: A reply. The Economic Journal, 86(343), 604–607.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Steedman, I. (1976b). Positive profits with negative surplus value: A reply to Wolfstetter. The Economic Journal, 86(344), 873–876.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Steedman, I. (1979a). Trade amongst growing economies. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Steedman, I. (Ed.). (1979b). Fundamental issues in trade theory. London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Steedman, I. (1979c). The von Neumann analysis and the small open economy. In I. Steedman (Ed.), Fundamental issues in trade theory (pp. 142–158). London: Macmillan.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Steedman, I. (1982). Joint production and the wage–rent frontier. The Economic Journal, 92(366), 377–385.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Steedman, I. (1985). Joint production and technical progress. Political Economy. Studies in the Surplus Approach, 1(1), 127–138.

    Google Scholar 

  • Steedman, I. (1992). Joint production and the “New Solution” to the transformation problem. Indian Economic Review, 27, Special number in memory of Sukhamoy Chakravarty, 123–127.

    Google Scholar 

  • Steedman, I. (1999). Production of commodities by means of commodities and the open economy. Metroeconomica, 50(3), 260–276. Reprinted in T. Cozzi & R. Marchionatti (Eds.). (2000). Piero Sraffa’s political economy: A centenary estimate (pp. 239–253). London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Steedman, I. (2005). The comparative statics of industry-level produced-input-use in HOS trade theory. Review of Political Economy, 17(3), 465–470.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Steedman, I. (2018). Foreign trade. In The new Palgrave. A dictionary of economics (3rd ed., pp. 4878–4887). London: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Steedman, I., & Metcalfe, J. S. (1973a). On foreign trade. Economia Internazionale/International Economics, 26(3–4), 516–528. Reprinted in I. Steedman (Ed.). (1979). Fundamental issues in trade theory (pp. 99–119). London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Steedman, I., & Metcalfe, J. S. (1973b). The non-substitution theorem and international trade theory. Australian Economic Papers, 12(21), 267–269. Reprinted in I. Steedman (Ed.). (1979). Fundamental issues in trade theory (pp. 123–126). London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Steedman, I., & Metcalfe, J. S. (1981). On duality and basic commodities in an open economy. Australian Economic Papers, 20(36), 133–141.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stefanidis, D. (1930). The inflow of foreign capital and its economic and political consequences. Thessaloniki (in Greek).

    Google Scholar 

  • Stolper, W. F., & Samuelson, P. A. (1941). Protection and real wages. The Review of Economic Studies, 9(1), 58–73.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tica, J., & Družić, I. (2006). The Harrod–Balassa–Samuelson effect: A survey of empirical evidence. EFZG Working Paper Series, No. 06–7/686, 1–38.

    Google Scholar 

  • von Neumann, J. (1937). Über ein ökonomisches Gleichungssystem und eine Verallgemeinerung des Brouwerschen Fixpunktsatzes. In K. Menger (Ed.), Ergebnisse eines Mathematischen Kolloquiums, 8 (pp. 73–83). Leipzig: Deuticke.

    Google Scholar 

  • von Neumann, J. (1945). A model of general economic equilibrium. The Review of Economic Studies, 13(1), 1–9.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2021 Springer Nature Singapore Pte Ltd.

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Mariolis, T., Rodousakis, N., Soklis, G. (2021). Value Theory, Joint Production, and International Trade Issues. In: Spectral Theory of Value and Actual Economies. Evolutionary Economics and Social Complexity Science, vol 24. Springer, Singapore. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-33-6260-4_4

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics