Skip to main content

Worker Training, Firm Productivity, and Trade Liberalization: Evidence from Chinese Firms

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
China’s Miracle in Foreign Trade

Part of the book series: Studies in Modern Chinese Economy ((SMCE))

  • 475 Accesses

Abstract

The present paper discuss a novel mechanism–worker training–that output trade liberalization affects firm productivity. With disaggregated Chinese firm-level production data from 2004 to 2006, we find strong evidence that output trade liberalization boost firm productivity. More importantly, after controlling for firm's self-selection to invest on worker training, our extensive empirical search suggests the following findings.

This chapter is coauthored with.Qing Liu and Larry Qiu and originally published in Developing Economies, 2017, 55(3), pp. 189–210.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 109.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 139.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 139.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    For example, the UK and Italy governments thought that, one of the key factors behind the loss of competitiveness of their firms in the global economy is the lack of training compared with other countries like Germany and Japan. Thus they initiated large training programs in their countries.

  2. 2.

    Aggregated data on the industrial sector in the annual China's Statistical Yearbook by the Natural Bureau of Statistics are compiled from this data set.

  3. 3.

    For example, information on some family-based firms, which usually have no formal accounting system in place, is based on a unit of one RMB, whereas the official requirement is a unit of 1000 RMB.

  4. 4.

    For example, observations are dropped if any of the following are true: : (1) liquid assets are greater than total assets; (2) total fixed assets are greater than total assets; (3) the net value of fixed assets is greater than total assets; (4) the firm's identification number is missing; or (5) an invalid established time exists (e.g., the opening month is later than December or earlier than January).

  5. 5.

    By separating firms into pure exporter (i.e., firms export all of their products), non-pure exporters (i.e., firms at most export some products), and non-exporters (i.e., firms do not export any products), we see that exporters spend more on worker training than non-exporters. Simultaneously, non-pure exporters have larger worker training expenses than pure exporters. Such results are not reported in the text but available upon request.

  6. 6.

    The data are from WTO webpage http://tariffdata.wto.org/ReportersAndProducts.aspx. Note that TRAINS data generally suffers from missing values problems, particularly regarding the tariffs imposed by other countries for Chinese exports. The product-destination-year combinations that have missing tariffs are hence dropped.

  7. 7.

    Specifically, foreign-invested enterprises (FIEs) include the following firms: foreign-invested joint-stock corporations (code: 310), foreign-invested joint venture enterprises (320), fully FIEs (330), foreign-invested limited corporations (340), Hong Kong/Macao/Taiwan of China (henceforth, H/M/T) joint-stock corporations (210), H/M/T joint venture enterprises (220), fully H/M/T-invested enterprises (230), and H/M/T-invested limited corporations (240). Appendix Table 10.5A presents the transitional probability for such foreign firms.

  8. 8.

    By the official definition reported in the China City Statistical Yearbook (2006), SOEs include firms such as domestic SOEs (code: 110), state-owned joint venture enterprises (141), and state-owned and collective joint venture enterprises (143), but exclude state-owned limited corporations (151). Appendix Table 10.5B presents the transitional probability for all SOEs.

  9. 9.

    Olley and Pakes (1996) show that the investment demand function is monotonically increasing in the productivity shock jt x, by making some mild assumptions about the firm's production technology.

  10. 10.

    Note that here the non-linear least squares approach is adopted to estimate (2-step) since it requires the estimated coefficients of the log-capital in the first and second term to be identical (Pavcnik, 2002).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Miaojie Yu .

Appendix A

Appendix A

Measuring Ex-ante TFP (TFP2)

This section draws heavily from Qiu and Yu (2013) to discuss how we construct and measure TFP using two different approaches: ex-post TFP (TFP1) and ex-ante TFP (TFP2) inspired by Feenstra et al. (2014).

We extend the Olley-Pakes (1996) approach to fit with China's reality in the following ways. Firstly, given that the measure of TFP requires real terms of firm's inputs (labor and capital) and output, we adopt different price deflators for inputs and outputs from Brandt et al. (2012) in which the output deflators are constructed using “reference price” information from China's Statistical Yearbooks whereas input deflators are constructed based on output deflators and China's national input-output table (2002).

Secondly, we take China's WTO accession in 2001 into account since such a positive demand shock would push Chinese firms to expand their economic scales, which in turn can exaggerate the simultaneous bias of their measured TFP. Thirdly, it is essential to construct the real investment variable when using the Olley-Pakes (1996) approach. As usual, we adopt the perpetual inventory method to investigate the law of motion for real capital and real investment. Different from assigning an arbitrary number for the depreciation ratio, we use the exact firm's real depreciation provided by the Chinese firm-level data set.

Finally, we also consider firm's processing behavior in the TFP realization by constructing a processing export indicator (one denotes processing export and zero otherwise). The idea is that processing firms may use different technology than non-processing firms (Feenstra and Hanson, 2005).

Thus, a firm's investment function is

$$ V_{it} = g_{1} (x_{it} ,\ln K_{it} ,EX_{it} ,PE_{it} ,WTO_{t} ) $$

where EXit,(PEit) is the export (processing export) indicator to measure whether firm i exports (engages in processing exports) in year t, and WTOt is an indicator that equals one if the WTO agreement has occurred after 2001 and zero before that. Therefore, inverting the investment function with respect to its first argument we obtainFootnote 9:

$$ x_{it} = g_{1}^{ - 1} (V_{it} ,\ln K_{it} ,EX_{it} ,PE_{it} ,WTO_{t} ) $$

Given the gross production function

$$ \ln Y_{it} = \alpha_{k} \ln K_{it} + \alpha_{l} \ln L_{it} + \alpha_{m} \ln M_{it} + x_{it} + \varepsilon_{it} $$

and defining the function \(g_{2} ( \cdot )\) as \(\alpha_{k} \ln K_{jt} + g_{1}^{ - 1} (V_{it} ,\,\ln K_{it} ,\,EX_{it} ,\,PE_{it} ,\,WTO_{t} )\), the estimation of the labor (materials) coefficients \(\alpha_{m}\) (\(\alpha_{m}\)) are obtained as:

$$ \ln Y_{it} = \alpha_{l} \ln L_{it} + \alpha_{m} \ln M_{it} + g_{2} (V_{it} ,\ln K_{it} ,EX_{it} ,PE_{it} ,WTO_{t} ) + \varepsilon_{it} $$

The next step is to obtain an unbiased estimated coefficient of \(\alpha_{k}\) Olley-Pakes (1996) use the following specification:

$$ \ln Y_{ir} - \hat{\alpha }_{l} \ln L_{it} - \hat{\alpha }_{m} \ln M_{it} = \alpha_{k} \ln K_{it} + E(x_{it} |x_{it - 1} ,pr_{it} ) + [x_{it} - E(x_{it} |x_{it - 1} ,pr_{it} )] + \varepsilon_{it} $$

where the estimated values of the labor coefficient and materials coefficient are used on the left. The expectation of productivity appearing in (2-step) is modeled as a forth-order polynomial function of lagged productivity, which can be obtained as (g2i,t-1-\(\alpha_{k}\)ln Ki,t-1), and also the predicted probability of the firm's survival into the year t, prit , based on year t-1 information. The predicted probability is obtained from Probit estimation.Footnote 10 The term [xit-E(xit| xit-1, prit)] is the productivity shock for surviving firms, but does not affect the investment or exit choice so it is treated as an error.

Once the coefficient of capital \(\hat{\alpha }_{k}\) is estimated in Eq. (10.2-step), it is ready to obtain the standard ex-post TFP:

$$ TFP1_{it} \equiv x_{it} = \ln Y_{it} - \hat{\alpha }_{k} \ln K_{it} - \hat{\alpha }_{l} \ln L_{it} - \hat{\alpha }_{m} \ln M_{it} $$

In this way, TFP1 includes both true production productivity and managerial efficiency. By contrast, the ex-ante productivity (TFP2) which only capture true production productivity is given by

$$ TFP2_{it} = g_{1}^{ - 1} (V_{it} ,\ln K_{it} ,EX_{it} ,PE_{it} ,WTO_{t} ) $$

Appendix Table 10.A1 reports the estimated coefficients of labor, capital, materials, TFP1 and TFP2.

Table 10.A1 Total factor productivity of Chinese firms (2000–2007)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2022 Truth and Wisdom Press

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Yu, M. (2022). Worker Training, Firm Productivity, and Trade Liberalization: Evidence from Chinese Firms. In: China’s Miracle in Foreign Trade. Studies in Modern Chinese Economy. Springer, Singapore. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-16-6030-6_10

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-16-6030-6_10

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Singapore

  • Print ISBN: 978-981-16-6029-0

  • Online ISBN: 978-981-16-6030-6

  • eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics