Skip to main content

Objective Functions of Islamic Bank Bangladesh: A Critique of Islamic Economics

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Islamic Economics as Mesoscience
  • 114 Accesses

Abstract

The failure of Islamic banks in general that is exemplified by Islamic Bank Bangladesh is pointed out by their absence of any true direction of wellbeing in the Tawhidi sense of methodology of organic unity of theory and application. In the end, Islamic banks as exemplified by the case of Islamic banks Bangladesh, are shown to be capitalist shareholding banks with blind reliance on shari’ah as human concocted jurisdictional approach contrary to the Tawhidi methodological worldview. Consequently, many of the actions by IBBL under the guidance of Islamic Development Bank (IDB) and Organization of Islamic Conferences (OIC) while claiming to be Islamically legitimate are flawed. There remain much room for improvement to know the legitimate understanding in accordance with the Tawhidi law.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

eBook
USD 16.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Choudhury (1987).

  2. 2.

    Lozano (2002).

  3. 3.

    Hammond (1989), Harsanyi (1955).

  4. 4.

    Islamic Bank Bangladesh Limited (2019).

  5. 5.

    IDB (Saudi Arabia), Kuwait Finance House (Kuwait), Jordan Islamic Bank (Jordan), Islamic Investment & Exchange Corporation (Qatar), Bahrain Islamic Bank (Bahrain), Islamic Banking System International Holding (Luxembourg), Al-Rajhi Company for Currency Exchange & Commerce (Saudi Arabia), Dubai Islamic Bank (Dubai), Public Institution of Social Security (Kuwait), Ministry of Awqaf and Islamic Affairs (Kuwait), Ministry of Justice, Department of Minors Affairs (Kuwait).

  6. 6.

    Choudhury (1988).

  7. 7.

    Kaku (2015, p. 43) writes: “Consciousness is the process of creating a model of the world using multiple feedback loops in various parameters (e.g. in temperatures, space, time, and in relation to others), in order to accomplish a goal (e.g. find mates, food, shelter).” Kaku calls the above definition of phenomenological consciousness as the ‘space–time theory of consciousness’. In our book consciousness (phenomenology) will be referred to in terms of the spanning over knowledge, space, and time dimensions.

  8. 8.

    MacPherson (n.d.).

  9. 9.

    Cadbury (2000).

  10. 10.

    Transparency International (2018).

  11. 11.

    The shari’ah independently distributed model: (Religion) + (intellect) + (family) + (progeny) + (property). We note that there is no circularity of relations between the component parts in such a utilitarian additive expression. Shari’ah therefore does not invoke the highest watermark of protection of religion (monotheism) in going about calling upon any of the other components without relational linkages between them. Note thereby, that in calling upon the component of property right, IBBL emphasises its shareholding model rather than the ‘Business Model’ of stakeholders’ wellbeing. IBBL raised by shari’ah on financial matters emphasises product development by referring to it as shari’ah compliance. Yet the element of progenitor wellbeing is missed out by ignoring the meaning of intertemporal valuation of present decisions. Indeed, all of shari’ah-based ‘Islamic’ banking has become an exercise in product development. An example of such a case is upholding of Islamic insurance (takaful) without intertemporal pricing of premium. Another example is of waqf (endowment or perpetual charity) in educational institution without examining the relevance of such an institution for grassroots educational development but religious purpose (Azha, Baharuddin, Sayurno, & Salahuddin, 2013).

    Contrarily, the Tawhidi worldview of monotheism reflected in organic unity of knowledge by inter-causal relations of wellbeing is W(x(θ), θ = f((Religion) × (intellect) × (family) × (progeny) × (property)), approximating to the quantitative evaluation of θ = θW(x(θ)). The evaluation complex system of interaction, integration, and evolutionary learning is explained by the non-linear forms of the inter-causal relations between the endogenous variables of the vector x(θ). The function ‘f’ explains families of extension of the five basic values as shown. A similar causal system model, but by method only and not the methodology of the Tawhidi genre of unity of knowledge, was given by Simon (1957).

  12. 12.

    Barquero (2007).

  13. 13.

    Qur’an (16:97): “Whoever works righteousness, whether male or female, while he (or she) is a true believer (of Islamic Monotheism) verily, to him We will give a good life (in this world with respect, contentment and lawful provision), and We shall pay them certainly a reward in proportion to the best of what they used to do (i.e. Paradise in the Hereafter).”.

  14. 14.

    Burstein (1991).

  15. 15.

    Choudhury (2018).

  16. 16.

    Yeager (1983).

  17. 17.

    Ghazanfar (1995).

  18. 18.

    Rodinson (2007).

  19. 19.

    Waltham (2010).

  20. 20.

    Lancaster (1966).

  21. 21.

    In the case of θ-induction in microeconomic sense, investment is disaggregate by projects, sectors, diversifications, and modes of financing. Besides, in terms of the inter-causality between various investment outlets (i, j), we denote such investment function by, Iij(xij(θ), θ) = ∏ijxijaij(θ) ⋅ θbij ⋅ {xij(θ)}-vector comprises all morally/ethically embedded material choices in the presence of their interaction, integration, and evolutionary learning by linkages. This expression can next be written in the log-linear form with non-linearity caused by θ-induced coefficients, aij, bij, i, j + 1, 2, …, n. Iij(xij(θ), θ) is a system of circular causation relations of the wellbeing function.

  22. 22.

    Sardar (1984).

  23. 23.

    Roy (2006).

  24. 24.

    Qur’an (45:18): Then We put you, [O Muhammad], on an ordained way concerning the matter [of religion]; so follow it and do not follow the inclinations of those who do not know.

  25. 25.

    Chittick (1989).

References

  • Azha, L., Baharuddin, S., Sayurno, & Salahuddin, S. S. (2013). The practice and management of waqf education in Malaysia. Procedia-Social and Behavioural Sciences, 90, 22–30.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barquero, A. V. (2007). Endogenous development, theories and policies of territorial development. Investigaciones Regionales, 11, 183–210.

    Google Scholar 

  • Burstein, M. (1991). History versus equilibrium: Joan Robinson and time in economics. In I. H. Rima (Ed.), The Joan Robinson legacy (pp. 49–61). Armonk, New York: M.E. Sharpe, Inc.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cadbury, A. (2000). H:\ALL\RESEARCH PAPERS\Corporate Governance and Food Price papers\Corporate Governance Definitions.htm.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chittick, W. C. (1989). Sufi path of knowledge. Albany, NY: State University of New York Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Choudhury, M. A. (1987). Microeconomic foundations of Islamic economics as a study in social economics. American Journal of Islamic Social Sciences, 3, 2.

    Google Scholar 

  • Choudhury, M. A. (1988). The conflict between efficiency and equity goals in manpower economics. Forum for Social Economics, 17, 2.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Choudhury, M. A. (2018). Comparative Islamic perspectives in money, monetary policy, and social wellbeing. Journal of Economic Cooperation and Development, 39(1), 143–162.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ghazanfar, S. M. (1995). History of economic thought: The Schumpeterian ‘Great Gap’, the ‘lost Arab-Islamic legacy, and the literature gap. Journal of Islamic Studies, 6(2), 234–253.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hammond, P. J. (1989). On reconciling Arrow’s theory of social choice with Harsanyi’s fundamental utilitarianism. In G. R. Feiwel (Ed.), Arrow and the foundation of the theory of economic policy (pp. 179–221). London, England: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harsanyi, J. C. (1955). Cardinal welfare, individualistic ethics, and interpersonal comparisons of utility. Journal of Political Economy, 63.

    Google Scholar 

  • Islamic Bank Bangladesh Limited. (2019). Annual Report 2017. Dhaka, Bangladesh.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kaku, M. (2015). Consciousness—A physicist’s viewpoint. In The future of the mind, Chapter 2. New York, NY: Anchor Book.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lancaster, K. J. (1966). A new approach to consumer theory. Journal of Political Economy, 74(2), 132–157.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lozano, J. M. (2002). Organizational ethics. In L. Zsolnai (Ed.), Ethics in the economy, handbook of business ethics (pp. 165–186). New York, NY: Peter Lang.

    Google Scholar 

  • MacPherson I. (n.d.). Patterns in the maritime cooperative movement 1900–1945. Acadiensis. Retrieved May 22, 2019, from https://journals.lib.unb.ca/index.php/Acadiensis/article/viewFile/11395/12145.

  • Rodinson, M. (2007). Islam and capitalism. London, England: SAQI Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Roy, O. (2006). Globalized Islam, the search for a New Ummah. New York, NY: Columbia University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sardar, Z. (1984). Islamisation of knowledge, or the Westernisation of Islam? Inquiry, 1, 7.

    Google Scholar 

  • Simon, H. (1957). Models of man. New York, NY: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Transparency International. (2018). Corruption perceptions index 2017. Retrieved March 6, 2018, from www.transparency.org.

  • Waltham, L. (2010). Marketplace of the Gods, how economics explains religion. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yeager, L. B. (Spring, 1983). Stable money and free-market currencies. CATO Journal, 305–326.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Masudul Alam Choudhury .

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2020 The Editor(s) (if applicable) and The Author(s), under exclusive license to Springer Nature Singapore Pte Ltd.

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Choudhury, M.A. (2020). Objective Functions of Islamic Bank Bangladesh: A Critique of Islamic Economics. In: Islamic Economics as Mesoscience. Springer, Singapore. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-15-6054-5_5

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-15-6054-5_5

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Singapore

  • Print ISBN: 978-981-15-6053-8

  • Online ISBN: 978-981-15-6054-5

  • eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics