Skip to main content

Wealth Transfers, Indifference Pricing, and XVA Compression Schemes

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
From Probability to Finance

Abstract

Since the 2008–2009 financial crisis, banks have introduced a family of XVA metrics to quantify the cost of counterparty risk and of its capital and funding implications: the credit/debt valuation adjustment (CVA and DVA), the costs of funding variation margin (FVA) and initial margin (MVA), and the capital valuation adjustment (KVA). We revisit from a wealth conservation and wealth transfer perspective at the incremental trade level the cost-of-capital XVA approach developed at the level of the balance sheet of the bank in [10]. Trade incremental XVAs reflect the wealth transfers triggered by the deals due to the incompleteness of counterparty risk. XVA-inclusive trading strategies achieve a given hurdle rate to shareholders in the conservative limit case that no new trades occur. XVAs represent a switch of paradigm in derivative management, from hedging to balance sheet optimization. This is illustrated by a review of possible applications of the XVA metrics.

This research has been conducted with the support of the Research Initiative “Modélisation des Marchés actions, obligations et dérivés” financed by HSBC France under the aegis of the Europlace Institute of Finance. The views and opinions expressed in this presentation are those of the author alone and do not necessarily reflect the views or policies of HSBC Investment Bank, its subsidiaries or affiliates. The research of Marc Chataigner is co-supported by a public grant as part of investissement d’avenir project, reference ANR-11-LABX-0056-LLH LabEx LMH.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

eBook
USD 19.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 29.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 29.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. 1.

    cf. Sect. 3.6.

  2. 2.

    Prices of spanning instruments at future time points of different scenarios, from which expected exposure profiles are easily deduced.

  3. 3.

    Hedging of spread risks, as jump-to-default risk can hardly be hedged.

  4. 4.

    In the sense of Assumption 2.9.

  5. 5.

    Counted, sign-wise, as a debt to the other clearing members.

  6. 6.

    Source: David Bachelier, panel discussion Capital & margin optimisation, Quantminds International 2018 conference, Lisbon, 16 May 2018.

References

  1. Abbas-Turki, L., Diallo, B., Crépey, S.: XVA principles, nested Monte Carlo strategies, and GPU optimizations. Int. J. Theor. Appl. Financ. 21, 1850030 (2018)

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  2. Albanese, C., Andersen, L.: Accounting for OTC derivatives: funding adjustments and the re-hypothecation option. Working paper (2014). https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2482955

  3. Albanese, C., Andersen, L.: FVA: what’s wrong, and how to fix it. Risk Mag. 54–56 (2015)

    Google Scholar 

  4. Albanese, C., Andersen, L., Iabichino, S.: FVA: accounting and risk management. Risk Mag. 64–68 (2015). Long preprint version available as https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2517301

  5. Albanese, C., Armenti, Y., Crépey, S.: XVA Metrics for CCP Optimisation. Statistics & Risk Modeling. (preprint on https://math.maths.univ-evry.fr/crepey) (2020)

  6. Albanese, C., Bellaj, T., Gimonet, G., Pietronero, G.: Coherent global market simulations and securitization measures for counterparty credit risk. Quant. Financ. 11(1), 1–20 (2011)

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  7. Albanese, C., Brigo, D., Oertel, F.: Restructuring counterparty credit risk. Int. J. Theor. Appl. Financ. 16(2), 1350010 (29 p) (2013)

    Google Scholar 

  8. Albanese, C., Caenazzo, S., Crépey, S.: Credit, funding, margin, and capital valuation adjustments for bilateral portfolios. Probab. Uncertain. Quant. Risk 2(7), 26 (2017)

    Google Scholar 

  9. Albanese, C., Crépey, S.: Capital valuation adjustment and funding valuation adjustment. Working paper (2019). https://math.maths.univ-evry.fr/crepey. (First, very preliminary version: arXiv:1603.03012 and ssrn.2745909, March 2016)

  10. Albanese, C., Crépey, S., Hoskinson, R., Saadeddine, B.: XVA analysis from the balance sheet. Working Paper (2019). https://math.maths.univ-evry.fr/crepey

  11. Antonov, A., Issakov, S., McClelland, A., Mechkov, S.: Pathwise XVA Greeks for early-exercise products. Risk Magazine (January) (2018)

    Google Scholar 

  12. Armenti, Y., Crépey, S.: Central clearing valuation adjustment. SIAM J. Financ. Math. 8(1), 274–313 (2017)

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  13. Balling, M.: Modigliani–Miller, Basel 3 and CRD 4. SUERF Policy Notes 2(1), 1–8 (2015)

    Google Scholar 

  14. Baron, D.: Default risk and the Modigliani–Miller theorem: a synthesis. Am. Econ. Rev. 66(1), 204–212 (1976)

    Google Scholar 

  15. Basel Committee on Banking Supervision: Consultative document: fundamental review of the trading book: a revised market risk framework (2013). http://www.bis.org/publ/bcbs265.pdf

  16. Basel Committee on Banking Supervision: Consultative document: application of own credit risk adjustments to derivatives (2012)

    Google Scholar 

  17. Bichuch, M., Capponi, A., Sturm, S.: Arbitrage-free XVA. Math. Financ. 28(2), 582–620 (2018)

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  18. Brigo, D., Pallavicini, A.: Nonlinear consistent valuation of CCP cleared or CSA bilateral trades with initial margins under credit, funding and wrong-way risks. J. Financ. Eng. 1, 1–60 (2014)

    MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  19. Burgard, C., Kjaer, M.: In the balance. Risk Magazine, pp. 72–75 (2011)

    Google Scholar 

  20. Burgard, C., Kjaer, M.: Funding costs, funding strategies. Risk Magazine, pp. 82–87. Preprint version (2013). https://ssrn.com/abstract=2027195

  21. Burgard, C., Kjaer, M.: Derivatives funding, netting and accounting. Risk Magazine, March 100–104. Preprint version (2017). https://ssrn.com/abstract=2534011

  22. Cline, W.: Testing the Modigliani–Miller theorem of capital structure irrelevance for banks. Peterson Institute for International Economics Working Paper Series (2015)

    Google Scholar 

  23. Committee of European Insurance and Occupational Pensions Supervisors. QIS5 technical specifications (2010). https://eiopa.europa.eu/Publications/QIS/QIS5-technical_specifications_20100706.pdf

  24. Crépey, S., Sabbagh, W., Song, S.: When capital is a funding source: the XVA anticipated BSDEs. SIAM J. Financ Math. Forthcoming (2020)

    Google Scholar 

  25. Duffie, D., Sharer, W.: Equilibrium and the role of the firm in incomplete market. Stanford University, Working Paper No. 915 (1986). https://www.gsb.stanford.edu/faculty-research/working-papers/equilibrium-role-firm-incomplete-markets

  26. Eisele, K.-T., Artzner, P.: Multiperiod insurance supervision: top-down models. Eur. Actuar. J. 1(1), 107–130 (2011)

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  27. European Parliament: Regulation (EU) no 648/2012 of the European parliament and of the council of 4 July 2012 on OTC derivatives, central counterparties and trade repositories (2012). http://eur-lex.europa.eu/LexUriServ/LexUriServ.do?uri=OJ:L:2012:201:0001:0059:EN:PDF

  28. Gottardi, P.: An analysis of the conditions for the validity of Modigliani–Miller Theorem with incomplete markets. Econ. Theory 5, 191–207 (1995)

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  29. Green, A., Kenyon, C.: Efficient XVA management: pricing, hedging, and allocation using trade-level regression and global conditioning (2014). arXiv:1412.5332v2

  30. Green, A., Kenyon, C., Dennis, C.: KVA: capital valuation adjustment by replication. Risk Magazine, pp. 82–87 (2014). Preprint version KVA: capital valuation adjustment available at https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2400324

  31. Hagen, K.: Default risk, homemade leverage, and the Modigliani–Miller theorem: note. Am. Econ. Rev. 66(1), 199–203 (1976)

    Google Scholar 

  32. Hellwig, M.: Bankruptcy, limited liability, and the Modigliani–Miller theorem. Am. Econ. Rev. 71(1), 155–170 (1981)

    Google Scholar 

  33. Huge, B., Savine, A.: LSM Reloaded—differentiate xVA on your iPad Mini (2017). https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2966155

  34. International Financial Reporting Standards: IFRS 13 fair value measurement (2012). http://www.iasplus.com/en/news/2011/May/news6909

  35. International Financial Reporting Standards: IFRS 4 insurance contracts exposure draft (2013)

    Google Scholar 

  36. Miller, M.: The Modigliani–Miller propositions after thirty years. J. Econ. Perspect. 2(4), 99–120 (1988)

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  37. Miller, M.: Do the M & M propositions apply to banks? J. Bank. Financ. 19, 483–489 (1995)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  38. Milne, F.: Choice over asset economies: default risk and corporate leverage. J. Financ. Econ. 2(2), 165–185 (1975)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  39. Modigliani, F., Miller, M.: The cost of capital, corporation finance and the theory of investment. Econ. Rev. 48, 261–297 (1958)

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  40. Salzmann, R., Wüthrich, M.: Cost-of-capital margin for a general insurance liability runoff. ASTIN Bull. 40(2), 415–451 (2010)

    MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  41. Swiss Federal Office of Private Insurance: Technical document on the Swiss solvency test (2006). https://www.finma.ch/FinmaArchiv/bpv/download/e/SST_techDok_061002_E_wo_Li_20070118.pdf

  42. Villamil, A.: The Modigliani–Miller theorem. In: The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics (2008). http://www.econ.uiuc.edu/~avillami/course-files/PalgraveRev_ModiglianiMiller_Villamil.pdf

  43. Williams, J.B.: The Theory of Investment Value. Harvard University Press, Cambridge (1938)

    Google Scholar 

  44. Wüthrich, M., Merz, M.: Financial Modeling, Actuarial Valuation and Solvency in Insurance. Springer, Berlin (2013)

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Stéphane Crépey .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendix: Connections with the Modigliani–Miller Theory

Appendix: Connections with the Modigliani–Miller Theory

The Modigliani–Miller celebrated invariance result is in fact not one but several related propositions, developed in a series of papers going back to the seminal [39] paper. These propositions are different facets of the broad statement that the funding and capital structure policies of a firm are irrelevant to the profitability of its investment decisions. See e.g. [14, 36, 42] for various discussions and surveys. We emphasize that we do not need or use such result (or any negative form of it) in our paper, but there are interesting connections to it, which we develop in this section.

1.1 Modigliani–Miller Irrelevance, No Arbitrage, and Completeness

Modigliani–Miller (MM) irrelevance, as we put it for brevity hereafter, was initially understood by its authors as a pure arbitrage result. They even saw this understanding as their main contribution with respect to various precedents, notably [43]’s law of conservation of investment value (see Sect. 2.3). So, quoting the footnote page 271 of [39]:

See, for example, Williams [21, esp. pp. 72–73]; David Durand [3]; and W. A. Morton [15]. None of these writers describe in any detail the mechanism which is supposed to keep the average cost of capital constant under changes in capital structure. They seem, however, to be visualizing the equilibrating mechanism in terms of switches by investors between stocks and bonds as the yields of each get out of line with their ‘riskiness.’ This is an argument quite different from the pure arbitrage mechanism underlying our proof, and the difference is crucial.

But, thirty years later, judging by the footnote page 99 in [36], the view of Miller on their result had evolved:

“For other, and in some respects, more general proofs of our capital structure proposition, see among others, Stiglitz (1974) for a general equilibrium proof showing that individual wealth and consumption opportunities are unaffected by capital structures; See Hirshleifer (1965) and (1966) for a state preference, complete-markets proof; Duffie and Shafer (1986) for extensions to some cases of incomplete markets”

Non-arbitrage and completeness are intersecting but non-inclusive notions. Hence, implicitly, in Miller’s own view, MM invariance does not hold in general in incomplete markets (even assuming no arbitrage opportunities). As a matter of fact, we can read page 197 of [28]:

“When there are derivative securities and markets are incomplete the financial decisions of the firm have generally real effects”

and page 9 of [25]:

“As to the effect of financial policy on shareholders, we point out that, generically, shareholders find the span of incomplete markets a binding constraint. This yields the obvious conclusion that shareholders are not indifferent to the financial policy of the firm if it can change the span of markets (which is typically the case in incomplete markets). We provide a trivial example of the impact of financial innovation by the firm. DeMarzo (1986) has gone beyond this and such earlier work as Stiglitz (1974), however, in showing that shareholders are indifferent to the trading of existing securities by firms. Anything the firm can do by trading securities, agents can undo by trading securities on their own account. Indeed, any change of security trading strategy by the firm can be accomodated within a new equilibrium that preserves consumption allocations. Hellwig (1981) distinguishes situations in which this is not the case, such as limited short sales.”

Regarding MM irrelevance or not in incomplete markets (including some of the references that appear in the above quotations and other less closely related ones): [14, 31, 32, 38] deal with the impact of the default riskiness of the firm; [13, 37] discuss the special case of banks, notably from the angle of the bias introduced by government repayment guarantees for bank demand deposits; [22] tests empirically MM irrelevance for banks, concluding to MM offsets of the order of half what they should be if MM irrelevance would fully hold.

1.2 The XVA Case

A bit like with limited short sales in [32], a (seemingly overlooked) situation where shareholders may “find the span of incomplete markets a binding constraint” is when market completion or, at least, the kind of completion that would be required for MM invariance to hold, is legally forbidden. This may seem a narrow situation but it is precisely the XVA case, which is also at the crossing between market incompleteness and the presence of derivatives pointed out as the MM ‘non irrelevance case’ in [28]. The contra-assets and contra-liabilities that emerge endogenously from the impact of counterparty risk on the derivative portfolio of a bank (cf. Definition 2.7) cannot be “undone” by shareholders, because jump-to-default risk cannot be replicated by a bank: This is practically impossible in the case of contra-assets, for lack of available or sufficiently liquid hedging instruments (such as CDS contracts with rapidly varying notional on corporate names that would be required for replicating CVA exposures at client defaults); It is even more problematic in the case of contra-liabilities, because a bank cannot sell CDS protection on itself (this is forbidden by law) and it has a limited ability in buying back its own debt (as, despite the few somehow provocative statements in [37], a bank is an intrinsically leveraged entity).

As a consequence, MM irrelevance is expected to break down in the XVA setup. In fact, as seen in the main body in the paper, cost of funding and cost of capital are material to banks and need be reflected in entry prices for ensuring shareholder indifference to the trades.

More precisely, the XVA setup is a case where a firm’s valuation is invariant to funding strategies and, still, investment decisions are not. The point here is a bit subtle. Saying that the value of a company is independent of financing strategies does not imply that investment decisions do not depend on financing strategies. There two numbers we can look at: the value of the equity \(\mathrm{E}\) and the sum of the value of equity and debt, \(\mathrm{E}+\mathrm{D}.\) Equity holders will naturally seek to optimize \(\mathrm{E}\) and will accept an investment opportunity if \(\varDelta \mathrm{E}\) is positive. Williams’ law implies that equity plus debt, \(\mathrm{E} + \mathrm{D}\), stays invariant under a certain financial transaction. But this does not imply in general that shareholders are indifferent to the transaction: Shareholders are indifferent if \(\varDelta \mathrm{E} = 0\), not if \(\varDelta (\mathrm{E}+\mathrm{D}) = 0\). To go from Williams’ wealth conservation law to MM irrelevance, we have to assume complete markets or, at least, the availability of certain trades to shareholders. Namely, assuming shareholders can and do change financing strategy, then, even if we start with \(\varDelta \mathrm{E} < 0 \) for a given transaction (but \(\varDelta (\mathrm{E}+\mathrm{D}) = 0\)), we may conclude that equity shareholders are actually indifferent as there exists a change in financing strategy for which \(\varDelta \mathrm{E} = 0\). However, in the XVA case, the bank cannot freely buy back its own debt, so such a change is not possible and only Williams’ wealth conservation law remains, whereas MM irrelevance breaks down: See Sect. 4 for illustration in a pedagogical static setup.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2020 Springer Nature Singapore Pte Ltd.

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Albanese, C., Chataigner, M., Crépey, S. (2020). Wealth Transfers, Indifference Pricing, and XVA Compression Schemes. In: Jiao, Y. (eds) From Probability to Finance. Mathematical Lectures from Peking University. Springer, Singapore. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-15-1576-7_5

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics