Skip to main content

Group Formation and Endogenous Information Collection in Microcredit

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
  • 269 Accesses

Abstract

This paper attempts to address the effects of different types of loan contract on a borrower’s incentive for investment in information. We model the trade-off that a borrower faces when she collects information about the potential of her intended projects both under individual and joint liability loan contracts. Even under limited liability, the borrower faces a trade-off at information collection stage between the cost of signal collection, and the cost of her time and effort for project execution in case the project fails. We show that joint liability contract induces borrowers to invest more in information than individual liability for low rates of interest. However, for some high rates of interest, borrowers invest positive amount in information collection under individual liability, but do not take up the project under joint liability.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD   109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD   109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    It is possible to consider other possible information structures. For example, we may consider the case when s is not publicly observable, but the quality of signal \(\left( \theta \right) \) is. In a richer model, we may take up the case when neither s nor \(\theta \) are publicly observable. In each of these cases, we can examine how the process of group formation is affected by the information structure. It will be further interesting to investigate the incentive for investment in quality of signal in all these three cases, and to observe how this incentive stands in comparison with individual liability.

  2. 2.

    Notice that a borrower’s decision about taking up the project depends on the signal realization. So when the group is formed and signals are not observable, even if a borrower receives an S signal, she may not have access to loan if her partner receives an F and decides against loan in a two member group. This is an inefficiency that arises when only group-based contracts are offered. A richer model should take this into account and allow the lender to offer both type of contracts at the same time. However, in this chapter, we analyze individual lending and group lending separately. That means that we do not allow the lender to offer both individual contract and group-based contract at a time.

  3. 3.

    Since,

    $$ r>\left( Y-e\right) \Rightarrow e>\left( Y-r\right) \Rightarrow \left( \frac{ e}{Y-r}\right) >1. $$
  4. 4.

    The result follows from continuity of \(g_{1}^{I}\left( r\right) \) and \( g_{1}^{I}\left( Y-e\right) <0\) while \(g_{1}^{I}\left( Y-2e\right) >0\). We have omitted the proof which is available from the authors on request.

  5. 5.

    It is easy to show that

    $$ \frac{\delta }{\delta r}\left( \text {LHS}\right) =-\left( 1-\theta ^{2}\right) \le 0 $$

    for all \(\theta \) and

    $$ \frac{\delta }{\delta \theta }\left( \text {LHS}\right) =-Y+2\theta r\le 0 $$

    since \(\theta \in \left[ \frac{1}{2},1\right] \) and \(r<\frac{Y}{2}\).

  6. 6.

    For the second-order condition, we need to assume that \(c\left( .\right) \) is sufficiently convex everywhere. This can be ensured if we assume that for the relavant values of r, \(c^{\prime \prime }\left( \theta \right) >r\). If we assume that \(c^{\prime \prime }\left( \theta \right) >\frac{Y}{2}\) for all \(\theta \in \left[ \frac{1}{2},1\right] \), then the SOC will always be satisfied.

  7. 7.

    We are not losing much by making this assumption. If it does not hold, then we may have multiple local maxima for relatively higher values of r. For any given value of r, the borrower would choose \(\theta \) that gives her highest expected utility among these local maximums. However, the value function (optimized expected utility function) will be continuous in r, though the optimal choice of \(\tilde{\theta }\left( r\right) \) would change discontinuously as r falls. When r is low enough, \(\tilde{\theta }\left( r\right) =\frac{1}{2}\). Unless we make the assumption mentioned above, there might be a range of r, in which \(\tilde{\theta }\left( r\right) >\frac{1}{2} \) and falls as r falls. Once r falls below a critical level, \(\tilde{\theta }\left( r\right) \) falls to \(\frac{1}{2}\) and remains there for all lower values of r.

References

  • Besley, T., & Coate, S. (1995). Group lending, repayment incentives and social collateral. Journal of Development Economics, 46, 1–18.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bhattacharya, S., Banerjee, S., & Mukherjee, S. (2008, March). Group lending and self help groups: Joint benefit as an alternative governance mechanism. The Journal of International Trade and Development, 17(1).

    Google Scholar 

  • Chowdhury, S., Roy Chowdhury P., & Sengupta, K. (2014). Sequential lending with dynamic joint liability in micro-finance, Discussion Papers in Economics, Discussion Paper 14-07. Indian Statistical Institute, Delhi, India.

    Google Scholar 

  • Conning, J. (1999). Outreach, sustainability and leverage in monitored and peer-monitored lending. Journal of Development Economics, 60, 51–77.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • de Aghion, B. A. (1999). On the design of a credit agreement with peer monitoring. Journal of Development Economics, 60, 79–104.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ghatak, M. (1999). Group lending, local information and peer selection. Journal of Development Economics, 60, 27–50.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ghatak, M., & Guinnane, T. W. (1999). The economics of lending with joint liability: Theory and practice. Journal of Development Economics, 60, 195–228.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ghosh, P., & Ray, D. (1997). Information and repeated interaction: Application to informal credit markets. Draft: Texas A & M and Boston University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Janvry, A., McIntosh, C., & Sadoulet, E. (2010). The supply and demand side impacts of credit market information. Journal of Development Economics, 93(2), 173–188.

    Google Scholar 

  • Morduch, J., & de Aghion, B. A. (2004a). Microfinance: Where do we stand. In C. Goodhart (Ed.), Financial development & economic growth: Explaining the links. London: Palgrave McMillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Morduch, J., & de Aghion, B. A. (2004b). Microfinance beyond group lending. The Economics of Transition, 8, 401–420.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mukherjee, S., & Bhattacharya, S. (2014). Optimal joint liability and group size in microcredit. Arthaniti-Journal of Economic Theory and Practice, 13(1–2), (19–47).

    Google Scholar 

  • Mukherjee, S., & Bhattacharya, S. (2015). Optimal group size under group lending with joint liability and social sanction. Indian Growth and Development Review, 8(1).

    Google Scholar 

  • Roy Chowdhury, P. (2005). Group lending: Sequential financing, lender monitoring and joint liability. Journal of Development Economics, 77, 415–439.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roy Chowdhury, P. (2007). Group-lending with sequential financing, contingent renewal and social capital. Journal of Development Economics, 84, 487–507.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sinha, F. (2005, April 23). Access, use and contribution of microfinance in India: Findings from a national study. Economic and Political Weekly, XL(17).

    Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz, J. E. (1990). Peer monitoring and credit markets. The World Bank Economic Review, 4, 351–366.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tsukada, K. (2012). Microfinance revisited: Towards a more flexible lending contracts. In A. Shonchoy (Ed.), Seasonality adjusted flexible micro-credit: An randomized experiment in Bangladesh, Interim Report. Chosakenkeu Hokokusho, IDE-JETRO 2012.

    Google Scholar 

  • Van Tassel, E. (1999). Group lending under asymmetric information. Journal of Development Economics, 60, 3–25.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Sukanta Bhattacharya .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendix

Appendix

Proof of Proposition 5 Notice that at \(r=r_{c}^{I}\),

$$ g_{1}\left( r\right) =\frac{1}{2}\left[ \hat{\theta }\left( r\right) \left( Y-r\right) -e\right] -c\left( \hat{\theta }\left( r\right) \right) =0 $$

and

$$\begin{aligned} g_{1}^{J}\left( r\right)= & {} \frac{1}{2}\left[ \hat{\theta }_{J}\left( r\right) \left( Y-r-(1-\hat{\theta }_{J}\left( r\right) )r\right) -e\right] -c\left( \hat{\theta }_{J}\left( r\right) \right) \\= & {} \frac{1}{2}\left[ \hat{\theta }_{J}\left( r\right) \left( Y-r\right) -e \right] -c\left( \hat{\theta }_{J}\left( r\right) \right) -\hat{\theta } _{J}\left( r\right) (1-\hat{\theta }_{J}\left( r\right) )r \\< & {} \frac{1}{2}\left[ \hat{\theta }_{J}\left( r\right) \left( Y-r\right) -e \right] -c\left( \hat{\theta }_{J}\left( r\right) \right) \le \frac{1}{2} \left[ \hat{\theta }\left( r\right) \left( Y-r\right) -e\right] -c\left( \hat{ \theta }\left( r\right) \right) \\= & {} 0 \end{aligned}$$

where the last inequality follows from the fact that \(\hat{\theta }\left( r\right) \) maximizes \(\left[ \frac{1}{2}\left[ \theta \left( Y-r\right) -e \right] \right. \left. -c\left( \theta \right) \right] \). Since \(g_{1}^{J}\left( r_{c}^{I}\right) <0\), \(\left( g_{1}^{J}\left( r\right) \right) ^{\prime }<0\) and \(g_{1}^{J}\left( r_{c}^{J}\right) =0\), it must be the case that \( r_{c}^{I}>r_{c}^{J}\) (please see, Fig. 3).

Suppose \(g\left( 0\right) <0\). Notice that

$$ g^{J}\left( r\right) =\frac{1}{2}\left[ \hat{\theta }_{J}\left( r\right) \left( Y-r-(1-\hat{\theta }_{J}\left( r\right) )r\right) -e\right] -c\left( \hat{\theta }_{J}\left( r\right) \right) -\left( \frac{Y}{2}-\frac{3r}{4} -e\right) $$

and

$$ g^{I}\left( r\right) =\frac{1}{2}\left[ \hat{\theta }\left( r\right) \left( Y-r\right) -e\right] -c\left( \hat{\theta }\left( r\right) \right) -\left( \frac{Y}{2}-\frac{r}{2}-e\right) $$

Hence, for any r, \(g^{J}\left( r\right) >g\left( r\right) \) if and only if

$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{1}{2}\left[ \hat{\theta }_{J}\left( r\right) \left( Y-r-(1-\hat{\theta }_{J}\left( r\right) )r\right) -e\right] -c\left( \hat{\theta }_{J}\left( r\right) \right) -\left( \frac{Y}{2}-\frac{3r}{4}-e\right) \\> & {} \frac{1}{2}\left[ \hat{\theta }\left( r\right) \left( Y-r\right) -e\right] -c\left( \hat{\theta }\left( r\right) \right) -\left( \frac{Y}{2}-\frac{r}{2} -e\right) \end{aligned}$$
$$ \Leftrightarrow \frac{r}{4}-\frac{1}{2}\hat{\theta }_{J}\left( r\right) (1- \hat{\theta }_{J}\left( r\right) )r>c\left( \hat{\theta }_{J}\left( r\right) \right) -c\left( \hat{\theta }\left( r\right) \right) -\left( \hat{\theta } _{J}\left( r\right) -\hat{\theta }\left( r\right) \right) \frac{Y-r}{2} $$

Now, the RHS of the above expression

$$\begin{aligned}&c\left( \hat{\theta }_{J}\left( r\right) \right) -c\left( \hat{\theta } \left( r\right) \right) -\left( \hat{\theta }_{J}\left( r\right) -\hat{\theta } \left( r\right) \right) \frac{Y-r}{2} \\= & {} \int \limits _{\hat{\theta }}^{\hat{\theta }_{J}}\left[ c^{\prime }\left( \theta \right) -\frac{Y-r}{2}\right] d\theta \\< & {} \int \limits _{\hat{\theta }}^{\hat{\theta }_{J}}\left[ c^{\prime }\left( \hat{\theta }_{J}\right) -\frac{Y-r}{2}\right] d\theta \end{aligned}$$

since \(c^{\prime \prime }\left( \theta \right) >0\). But from (11)

$$\begin{aligned} \int \limits _{\hat{\theta }}^{\hat{\theta }_{J}}\left[ c^{\prime }\left( \hat{\theta } _{J}\right) -\frac{Y-r}{2}\right] d\theta= & {} \int \limits _{\hat{\theta }}^{\hat{ \theta }_{J}}\left[ \frac{Y-2\left( 1-\hat{\theta }_{J}\right) r}{2}-\frac{Y-r }{2}\right] d\theta \\= & {} \int \limits _{\hat{\theta }}^{\hat{\theta }_{J}}\frac{\left( 2\hat{\theta } _{J}-1\right) r}{2}d\theta \\= & {} \left( \hat{\theta }_{J}-\frac{1}{2}\right) \left( \hat{\theta }_{J}-\hat{ \theta }\right) r \end{aligned}$$

We now show that for any \(r>0\),

$$ \frac{r}{4}-\frac{1}{2}\hat{\theta }_{J}(1-\hat{\theta }_{J})r>\left( \hat{ \theta }_{J}-\frac{1}{2}\right) \left( \hat{\theta }_{J}-\hat{\theta }\right) r\Leftrightarrow \frac{1}{2}>\hat{\theta }_{J}^{2}-2\hat{\theta }_{J}\hat{ \theta }+\hat{\theta } $$

which holds since \(\hat{\theta }_{J},\hat{\theta }\in \left( \frac{1}{2} ,1\right) \). Hence, we can conclude that for any \(r>0\), \(g^{J}\left( r\right) >g^{I}\left( r\right) \). Since, at \(r=r_{d}^{I}\), \(g^{I}\left( r\right) =0\), we can conclude that \(g^{J}\left( r_{d}^{I}\right) >0\). Since \( g^{J\prime }\left( r\right) >0\) and \(g^{J}\left( r_{d}^{J}\right) =0\), it must be the case that \(r_{d}^{J}<r_{d}^{I}\). The interest rate at which the borrower starts investing in signal quality is higher under individual liability.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2019 Springer Nature Singapore Pte Ltd.

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Bhattacharya, S., Mukherjee, S. (2019). Group Formation and Endogenous Information Collection in Microcredit. In: Bandyopadhyay, S., Dutta, M. (eds) Opportunities and Challenges in Development. Springer, Singapore. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-13-9981-7_8

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-13-9981-7_8

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Singapore

  • Print ISBN: 978-981-13-9980-0

  • Online ISBN: 978-981-13-9981-7

  • eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics