Skip to main content

Measures of Productivity Change

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Productivity and Efficiency Analysis
  • 2239 Accesses

Abstract

In this book, measures of productivity change are defined as measures of output quantity change divided by measures of input quantity change. Computing measures of output and input quantity change involves assigning numbers to baskets of outputs and inputs. The most distinguishing feature of this book is that it computes index numbers that are consistent with measurement theory. So please add the following to the end of this paragraph: Measurement theory says that so-called index numbers must be assigned in such a way that the relationships between the numbers mirror the relationships between the baskets. This chapter explains how to compute output and input quantity index numbers (and therefore productivity index numbers) that are consistent with measurement theory.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 89.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD 119.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. 1.

    Measurement theory is the study of how numbers are assigned to objects. Classical measurement theory holds that only quantitative attributes of objects are measurable. The representational theory of measurement holds that qualitative attributes of objects are also measureable. For more details, see Sarle (1997) , Hosch (2011, pp. 227–229) and Tal (2016, Sect. 3).

  2. 2.

    Similar distinctions can be found in other areas of science. In econometrics, for example, an estimator is a rule or formula that explains how to use data to estimate the value of a population parameter, while an estimate is the value obtained after data have been substituted into the formula. See, for example, Hill et al. (2011, p. 53).

  3. 3.

    This definition can be traced back at least as far as O’Donnell (2012a) . Elsewhere in the literature, output and input indices are rarely defined in terms of aggregate quantities. When they are, the aggregator functions are often observation-varying (e.g., they depend on observation-varying prices or value shares) and/or their monotonicity and homogeneity properties are not all specified. See, for example, Diewert (1976).

  4. 4.

    If some outputs are zero, then some output indices may be mathematically undefined and may therefore not satisfy some axioms.

  5. 5.

    These statements, and similar statements elsewhere in this chapter, are axioms in the sense that they are substantive assertions about elements of the domain of index number theory.

  6. 6.

    In O’Donnell (2016) , an output index is said to be proper if and only if eight axioms are satisfied. If QI4 and QI6 are satisfied, then, and only then, the extra two axioms of O’Donnell (2016) , an identity axiom and a circularity axiom, are also satisfied. The use of the term ‘proper’ in an index number context can be traced back to O’Donnell (2012b, p. 6).

  7. 7.

    If output distance functions and/or cost functions are unknown, then the choice set will obviously be limited. Samuelson and Swamy (1974) write that “we cannot hope for one ideal formula for the index number: if it works for the tastes of Jack Spratt, it won’t work for his wife’s tastes; if say, a Cobb-Douglas function can be found that works for him with one set of parameters and for her with another set, their daughter will in general require a non-Cobb-Douglas formula! Just as there is an uncountable infinity of different indifference contours—there is no counting tastes—there is an uncountable infinity of different index-number formulas, which dooms Fisher’s search for the ideal one. It does not exist even in Plato’s heaven.” (p. 568).

  8. 8.

    The use of the term ‘additive’ to describe an index of this type can be traced back at least as far as Aczel and Eichhorn (1974) . The index is additive in the sense that \(QI^A(q_{ks},q_{it}+q_{rl})=QI^A(q_{ks},q_{it})+QI^A(q_{ks},q_{rl})\) and \(1/QI^A(q_{ks}+q_{rl},q_{it})=1/QI^A(q_{ks},q_{it})+1/QI^A(q_{rl},q_{it})\) (Aczel and Eichhorn 1974 , p. 525).

  9. 9.

    Here, the term ‘mean-corrected’ means all variables have been re-scaled to have unit means.

  10. 10.

    The use of the term ‘multiplicative’ to describe an index of this type can be traced back at least as far as Coelli et al. (2005, p. 131) . The index is multiplicative in the sense that \(QI^M(q_{ks}\odot q_{gh},q_{it}\odot q_{rl})=QI^M(q_{ks},q_{it})QI^M(q_{gh},q_{rl})\).

  11. 11.

    Balk (1998, p. 100) also uses the term ‘primal’ in reference to an index that is constructed using an output distance function.

  12. 12.

    In production economics, the term ‘dual’ is usually used to describe cost, revenue and profit functions (e.g., Beavis and Dobbs 1990, p. 99).

  13. 13.

    Cherchye et al. (2007) attribute the term ‘benefit-of-the-doubt’ to Melyn and Moesen (1991).

  14. 14.

    The choice of one as the maximum aggregate output is arbitrary.

  15. 15.

    The BOD output index is a proper index, implying it satisfies a circularity axiom (among others). Characteristicity and circularity are generally in conflict with each other. Drechsler (1973, p.17) claims, incorrectly, that they are always in conflict with each other. This erroneous claim can be traced back to Fisher (1922, p. 275).

  16. 16.

    The right-hand side of this equation is a function of \(q_{ks},q_{it},p_{ks}\) and \(p_{it}\). However, only \(q_{ks}\) and \(q_{it}\) have been listed on the left-hand side. In this book, dots and ellipses are used in functions to indicate that one or more variables have been omitted.

  17. 17.

    If the output distance function is nondecreasing in outputs, then the partial derivatives of the distance function with respect to the outputs must be nonnegative for all feasible input-output combinations. If the output distance function is a translog function, then it is possible to find feasible input-output combinations such that at least one partial derivative is negative. Ergo, the output distance function cannot be a translog function.

  18. 18.

    The CNLS estimates of \(\tau \), \(\gamma _1\) and \(\gamma _2\) are 1, 0.0018 and 0.9982 respectively.

  19. 19.

    This definition can be traced back at least as far as O’Donnell (2012a) . See footnote 3 on p. 94.

  20. 20.

    If some inputs are zero, then some input indices may be mathematically undefined and may therefore not satisfy some axioms.

  21. 21.

    In O’Donnell (2016) , an input index is said to be proper if and only if eight axioms are satisfied. If XI1 to XI6 are satisfied, then, and only then, all eight of the O’Donnell (2016) axioms are satisfied.

  22. 22.

    Balk (1998, p. 59) also uses the term ‘primal’ in reference to an index that is constructed using an input distance function.

  23. 23.

    The choice of one as the minimum aggregate input is arbitrary.

  24. 24.

    If the input distance function is nondecreasing in inputs, then the partial derivative of the distance function with respect to the inputs must be nonnegative for all feasible input-output combinations. If the input distance function is a translog function, then it is possible to find feasible input-output combinations such that at least one partial derivative is negative. Ergo, the input distance function cannot be a translog function.

  25. 25.

    The CNLS estimates of \(\lambda _1\) and \(\lambda _2\) are 0.2367 and 0.7633 respectively.

  26. 26.

    If some outputs or inputs are zero, then some TFPIs may be either zero or mathematically undefined and may therefore not satisfy some axioms.

  27. 27.

    Bjurek (1996) defines his index in a time-series context. In such a context, all notation pertaining to firms can be suppressed.

  28. 28.

    The output distance functions that underpin the Caves et al. (1982a) index are firm-specific functions. A firm-specific output distance function is presumably a representation of a firm-specific output set. A firm-specific output set is presumably a set containing all outputs that can be produced by a given firm using given inputs. Thus, Caves et al. (1982a) presumably have in mind that it was technically possible for a given firm to transform a given input vector into a given output vector, but, because it operates in a different production environment, it was not technically possible for another firm to do the same. In contrast, Färe et al. (1994 , Eq.  6). define an ‘output-based Malmquist productivity change index’ in a time-series context. The output distance functions that define their index are period-specific functions. Thus, Färe et al. (1994) presumably have in mind that it was technically possible to transform a given input vector into a given output vector in a given period, but, because the requisite technologies may not have been developed, it may not have been technically possible to do the same thing in an earlier period.

  29. 29.

    In O’Donnell (2012b) , an output price index is said to be proper if and only if nine axioms are satisfied. If PI1 to PI6 are satisfied, then, and only then, eight of the O’Donnell (2012b) axioms are satisfied. If the aggregator function is differentiable, then the ninth axiom is also satisfied.

  30. 30.

    Balk and Diewert (2003) define their price index in a consumer context. According to Hill (2008, p. 2) , many consumer price indices produced by statistical agencies turn out to be Lowe indices.

  31. 31.

    A proof is given in Appendix A.1 (Proposition 19).

  32. 32.

    A proof is given in Appendix A.1 (Proposition 20).

  33. 33.

    A proof is given in Appendix A.1 (Proposition 21).

  34. 34.

    Some observers put these claims down to hubris. See, for example, Samuelson and Swamy (1974, p. 575).

  35. 35.

    Many of these authors use either the DPIN software of O’Donnell (2010a) or the R package of Dakpo et al. (2016) to compute ‘Färe-Primont’ TFPI numbers. In this book, these index numbers are viewed as additive index numbers obtained using estimated representative normalised shadow prices as weights.

References

  • Aczel J, Eichhorn W (1974) A note on additive indices. J Econ Theory 8(4):525–529

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anik AR, Rahman S, Sarker J (2017) Agricultural productivity growth and the role of capital in South Asia (1980–2013). Sustainability 9(3):470

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arjomandi A, Valadkhani A, O’Brien M (2014) Analysing banks’ intermediation and operational performance using the Hicks-Moorsteen TFP index: the case of Iran. Res Int Bus Finance 30:111–125

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arjomandi A, Salleh MI, Mohammadzadeh A (2015) Measuring productivity change in higher education: an application of Hicks-Moorsteen total factor productivity index to Malaysian public universities. J Asia Pac Econ 20(4):630–643

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arora H, Arora P (2013) Measuring and decomposing productivity change using Hicks-Moorsteen index numbers: evidence from Indian banks. Int J Prod Qual Manag 11(1):74–95

    Google Scholar 

  • Balk B (1998) Industrial price, quantity, and productivity indices: the micro-economic theory and an application. Kluwer Academic Publishers, Boston

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Balk B (2008) Price and quantity index numbers: models for measuring aggregate change and difference. Cambridge University Press, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Balk B, Diewert W (2003) The Lowe consumer price index and its substitution bias. Department of Economics Discussion Paper 04-07, University of British Colombia

    Google Scholar 

  • Ball V, Hallahan C, Nehring R (2004) Convergence of productivity: an analysis of the catch-up hypothesis within a panel of states. Am J Agric Econ 86(5):1315–1321

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bao H (2014) Provincial total factor productivity in Vietnamese agriculture and its determinants. J Econ Dev 16(2):5–20

    Google Scholar 

  • Baráth L, Fertö I (2017) Productivity and convergence in European agriculture. J Agric Econ 68(1):228–248

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beavis B, Dobbs I (1990) Optimization and stability theory for economic analysis. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Bjurek H (1996) The Malmquist total factor productivity index. Scand J Econ 98(2):303–313

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blancas F, Contreras I, Ramirez-Hurtado J (2013) Constructing a composite indicator with multiplicative aggregation under the objective of ranking alternatives. J Oper Res Soc 64(5):668–678

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Briec W, Kerstens K (2011) The Hicks-Moorsteen productivity index satisfies the determinateness axiom. Manch Sch 79(4):765–775

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Briec W, Kerstens K, Prior D, Van de Woestyne I (2018) Testing general and special Färe-Primont indices: a proposal for public and private sector synthetic indices of European regional expenditures and tourism. Eur J Oper Res (forthcoming)

    Google Scholar 

  • Carrington R, O’Donnell C, Rao D (2016) Australian university productivity growth and public funding revisited. Stud High Educ pp 1–22. https://doi.org/10.1080/03075,079.2016.1259,306

  • Caves D, Christensen L, Diewert W (1982a) The economic theory of index numbers and the measurement of input, output, and productivity. Econometrica 50(6):1393–1414

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caves D, Christensen L, Diewert W (1982b) Multilateral comparisons of output, input, and productivity using superlative index numbers. Econ J 92(365):73–86

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chambers R, Färe R, Grosskopf S (1996) Productivity growth in APEC countries. Pac Econ Rev 1(3):181–190

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cherchye L, Moesen W, Rogge N, van Puyenbroeck T (2007) An introduction to ‘benefit of the doubt’ composite indicators. Soc Indic Res 82(1):111–145

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cherchye L, Moesen W, Rogge N, van Puyenbroeck T, Saisana M, Saltelli A, Liska R, Tarantola S (2008) Creating composite indicators with DEA and robustness analysis: the case of the Technology Achievement Index. J Oper Res Soc 59(2):239–251

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coelli T, Rao D (2005) Total factor productivity growth in agriculture: a Malmquist index analysis of 93 countries, 1980–2000. Agric Econ 32(s1):115–134

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coelli T, Rao D, O’Donnell C, Battese G (2005) An introduction to efficiency and productivity analysis, 2nd edn. Springer, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Dakpo K, Desjeax Y, Latruffe L (2016) Productivity: indices of productivity using Data Envelopment Analysis (DEA). R Package Version 0.1.0, https://cran.r-project.org/web/packages/productivity/productivity.pdf

  • Daraio C, Simar L (2007) Advanced robust and nonparametric methods in efficiency analysis: methodology and applications. Springer, Berlin

    Google Scholar 

  • Deaza J, Gilles E, Vivas A (2016) Productivity measurements for South Korea and three countries of the Pacific Alliance: Colombia, Chile and Mexico, 2008–2012. Appl Econ Int Dev 16(2):75–92

    Google Scholar 

  • Despotis D (2005) A reassessment of the Human Development Index via data envelopment analysis. J Oper Res Soc 56(8):969–980

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diewert W (1976) Exact and superlative index numbers. J Econ 4(2):115–145

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diewert W (1992) Fisher ideal output, input, and productivity indexes revisited. J Prod Anal 3(3):211–248

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diewert W, Fox K (2017) Decomposing productivity indexes into explanatory factors. Eur J Oper Res 256(1):275–291

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Drechsler L (1973) Weighting of index numbers in multilateral international comparisons. Rev Income Wealth 19(1):17–34

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Economic Inisights (2014) Economic benchmarking assessment of operating expenditure for NSW and Tasmanian electricity TNSPs. Report prepared by Denis Lawrence, Tim Coelli and John Kain for the Australian Energy Regulator

    Google Scholar 

  • Elnasri A, Fox K (2017) The contribution of research and innovation to productivity. J Prod Anal 47(3):291–308

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elteto O, Koves P (1964) On a problem of index number computation relating to international comparison. Statisztikai Szemle 42:507–518

    Google Scholar 

  • Färe R, Grosskopf S (1990) The Fisher ideal index and the indirect Malmquist productivity index: a comparison. New Zealand Econ Pap 24(1):66–72

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Färe R, Primont D (1995) Multi-output production and duality: theory and applications. Kluwer Academic Publishers, Boston

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Färe R, Grosskopf S, Lindgren B, Roos P (1992) Productivity changes in Swedish pharmacies 1980–1989: a non-parametric Malmquist approach. J Prod Anal 3:85–101

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Färe R, Grosskopf S, Norris M, Zhang Z (1994) Productivity growth, technical progress, and efficiency change in industrialized countries. Am Econ Rev 84(1):66–83

    Google Scholar 

  • Fisher I (1922) The making of index numbers. Houghton Mifflin, Boston

    Google Scholar 

  • Fissel B, Felthoven R, Kaperski S, O’Donnell C (2015) Decomposing productivity and efficiency changes in the Alaska head and gut factory trawl fleet. Mar Policy. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.marpol.2015.06.018i

  • Fox K, Grafton Q, Kirkley J, Squires D (2003) Property rights in a fishery: regulatory change and firm performance. J Environ Econ Manage 46(1):156–177

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grifell-Tatjé E, Lovell C (1995) A note on the Malmquist productivity index. Econ Lett 47:169–175

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hicks J (1961) Measurement of capital in relation to the measurement of other economic aggregates. Macmillan, London

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Hill P (2008) Lowe indices. In: Paper presented at the 2008 World Congress on national accounts and economic performance measures for nations, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Hill R, Griffiths W, Lim G (2011) Principles of econometrics, 4th edn. Wiley, Hoboken

    Google Scholar 

  • Hosch W (ed) (2011) The britannica guide to numbers and measurement, 1st edn. Britannica Educational Publishing, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • IMF (2004) Producer price index manual: theory and practice. published for the ILO, IMF, OECD, UNECE and World Bank by the International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Islam N, Xayavong V, Kingwell R (2014) Broadacre farm productivity and profitability in South-Western Australia. Aust J Agric Resour Econ 58(2):147–170

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kerstens K, Van de Woestyne I (2014) Comparing the Malmquist and Hicks-Moorsteen productivity indices: Exploring the impact of unbalanced versus balanced panel data. Eur J Oper Res 233:749–758

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Khan F, Salim R, Bloch H (2015) Nonparametric estimates of productivity and efficiency change in Australian broadacre agriculture. Aust J Agric Resour Econ 59(3):393–411

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Khan F, Salim R, Bloch H, Islam N (2017) The public R&D and productivity growth in Australia’s broadacre agriculture: Is there a link? Aust J Agric Resour Econ 61(2):285–303

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kuosmanen T, Sipiläinen T (2009) Exact decomposition of the Fisher ideal total factor productivity index. J Prod Anal 31(3):137–150

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laurenceson J, O’Donnell CJ (2014) New estimates and a decomposition of provincial productivity change in China. China Econ Rev 30:86–97

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lawrence D, Diewert W, Fox K (2006) The contributions of productivity, price changes and firm size to profitability. J Prod Anal 26(1):1–13

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mahlberg B, Obersteiner M (2001) Remeasuring the HDI by data envelopment analysis. Interim Report IR-01-069, International Institute for Applied Systems Analysis (IIASA), Laxenburg, Austria

    Google Scholar 

  • Maniadakis N, Thanassoulis E (2004) A cost Malmquist productivity index. Eur J Oper Res 154(2):396–409

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Melyn W, Moesen W (1991) Towards a synthetic indicator of macroeconomic performance: unequal weighting when limited information is available. Public Economics Research Paper 17, CES, KU Leuven

    Google Scholar 

  • Mizobuchi H (2017) Productivity indexes under Hicks neutral technical change. J Prod Anal 48:63–68

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moorsteen R (1961) On measuring productive potential and relative efficiency. Q J Econ 75(3):151–167

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mugera A, Langemeier M, Ojede A (2016) Contributions of productivity and relative price change to farm-level profitability change. Am J Agric Econ 98(4):1210–1229

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • O’Donnell C (2010a) DPIN version 1.0: A program for decomposing productivity index numbers. Centre for Efficiency and Productivity Analysis Working Papers WP01/2010, University of Queensland

    Google Scholar 

  • O’Donnell C (2010b) Measuring and decomposing agricultural productivity and profitability change. Aust J Agric Resour Econ 54(4):527–560

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • O’Donnell C (2012a) An aggregate quantity framework for measuring and decomposing productivity change. J Prod Anal 38(3):255–272

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • O’Donnell C (2012b) Alternative indexes for multiple comparisons of quantities and prices. Centre for Efficiency and Productivity Analysis Working Papers WP05/2012 (Version 21 May 2013), University of Queensland

    Google Scholar 

  • O’Donnell C (2012c) Nonparametric estimates of the components of productivity and profitability change in U.S. agriculture. Am J Agric Econ 94(4):873–890

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • O’Donnell C (2013) Econometric estimates of productivity and efficiency change in the Australian northern prawn fishery. In: Mamula A, Walden J (eds) Proceedings of the National Marine Fisheries Service Workshop, U.S. Department of Commerce National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration

    Google Scholar 

  • O’Donnell C (2014) Econometric estimation of distance functions and associated measures of productivity and efficiency change. J Prod Anal 41(2):187–200

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • O’Donnell C (2016) Using information about technologies, markets and firm behaviour to decompose a proper productivity index. J Econ 190(2):328–340

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • O’Donnell C, Nguyen K (2013) An econometric approach to estimating support prices and measures of productivity change in public hospitals. J Prod Anal 40(3):323–335

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pan M, Walden J (2015) Measuring productivity in a shared stock fishery: a case study of the Hawaii longline fishery. Mar Policy 62:302–308

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rahman S (2007) Regional productivity and convergence in Bangladesh agriculture. J Dev Areas 41(1):221–236

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ray S, Mukherjee K (1996) Decomposition of the Fisher ideal index of productivity: a non-parametric dual analysis of US airlines data. Econ J 106(439):1659–1678

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson P, Swamy S (1974) Invariant economic index numbers and canonical duality: survey and synthesis. Am Econ Rev 64(4):566–593

    Google Scholar 

  • Sarle W (1997) Measurement theory: frequently asked questions. ftp://ftp.sas.com/pub/neural/measurement.html

  • See K, Coelli T (2013) Estimating and decomposing productivity growth of the electricity generation industry in Malaysia: a stochastic frontier analysis. Energy Policy 62(207–214)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • See K, Li F (2015) Total factor productivity analysis of the UK airport industry: a Hicks-Moorsteen index method. J Air Transp Manag 43(March):1–10

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sheng Y, Mullen J, Zhao S (2011) A turning point in agricultural productivity: consideration of the causes. Research Report 11.4, Australian Bureau of Agricultural and Resource Economics and Sciences

    Google Scholar 

  • Silva Portela M, Thanassoulis E (2006) Malmquist indexes using a geometric distance function (GDF). Application to a sample of Portuguese bank branches. J Prod Anal 25(1):25–41

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Suhariyanto K, Thirtle C (2001) Asian agricultural productivity and convergence. J Agric Econ 52(3):96–110

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Szulc B (1964) Indices for multi-regional comparisons. Prezeglad Statystyczny (Stat Rev) 3:239–254

    Google Scholar 

  • Tal E (2016) Measurement in science. In: Zalta EN (ed) The Stanford encyclopedia of philosophy, winter, 2016th edn. Stanford University, Metaphysics Research Lab

    Google Scholar 

  • Tozer P, Villano R (2013) Decomposing productivity and efficiency among Western Australian grain producers. J Agric Resour Econ 38(3):312–326

    Google Scholar 

  • Worthington A, Lee B (2008) Efficiency, technology and productivity change in Australian universities, 1998–2003. Econ Educ Rev 27(3):285–298

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Christopher J. O’Donnell .

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2018 Springer Nature Singapore Pte Ltd.

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

O’Donnell, C.J. (2018). Measures of Productivity Change. In: Productivity and Efficiency Analysis. Springer, Singapore. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-13-2984-5_3

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-13-2984-5_3

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Singapore

  • Print ISBN: 978-981-13-2982-1

  • Online ISBN: 978-981-13-2984-5

  • eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics