Skip to main content

On the Incentive for a Self-Interested Policymaker to Mimic the Behavior of a Social-Welfare Maximizer

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Book cover Recent Developments in Normative Trade Theory and Welfare Economics

Part of the book series: New Frontiers in Regional Science: Asian Perspectives ((NFRSASIPER,volume 26))

  • 304 Accesses

Abstract

We consider a government consisting of two policy implementation departments, each of which is self-interested. We examine whether each of these departments disguise itself as a social-welfare maximizer in the sense that it adopts welfare maximization as its “surface” objective to determine the policy variable, although its “true” objective is self-interest maximization under a tariff/subsidy scheme. We also examine whether an increase in the number of departments disguising themselves as welfare maximizers improves welfare. When the cost difference between home and foreign firms is at the intermediate level, the subsidy department does not disguise itself as a benevolent policymaker, whereas the tariff department may do so. In addition, the welfare level in the partial disguise case is lower than that in the no disguise case.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 79.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 99.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 129.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    In the literature on oligopolies, Fershtman and Judd (1987) showed that a duopolistic firm’s surface objective does not coincide with its true one in the sense that each firm owner seeking to maximize the firm’s profit presents his or her objective function, which is different from the firm’s profit, to his or her manager when the strategic variable (e.g., output) is determined. See also Vickers (1985).

  2. 2.

    In Brennan and Buchanan (1977), the government can be regarded as a Leviathan (i.e., a tax revenue maximizer). See also Niskanen (1971).

  3. 3.

    See Appendix 10.1 for the proof.

  4. 4.

    Larue and Gervais (2002) assumed that domestic firms are price leaders and that foreign firms are on the competitive fringe.

  5. 5.

    See Appendix 10.2 for the proof.

  6. 6.

    See Appendix 10.3 for the proof.

References

  • Baldwin, R. (1987). Politically realistic objective functions and trade policy. Economics Letters, 24, 287–290.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brander, J. A., & Spencer, B. J. (1985). Export subsidies and international market share rivalry. Journal of International Economics, 18, 83–100.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brennan, G., & Buchanan, J. M. (1977). Towards a tax constitution for Leviathan. Journal of Public Economics, 8, 255–273.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clark, R., & Collie, D. R. (2008). Maximum-revenue versus optimum-welfare export taxes: A delegation game. Review of International Economics, 16, 919–929.

    Google Scholar 

  • Collie, D. R. (1991). Optimum welfare and maximum revenue tariffs under oligopoly. Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 38, 398–401.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dixit, A. (1988). Anti-dumping and countervailing duties under oligopoly. European Economic Review, 32, 55–68.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eaton, J., & Grossman, G. M. (1986). Optimal trade and industrial policy under oligopoly. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 101, 383–406.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fershtman, C., & Judd, K. L. (1987). Equilibrium incentives in oligopoly. American Economic Review, 77, 927–940.

    Google Scholar 

  • Johnson, H. G. (1951−52). Optimum welfare and maximum revenue tariffs. Review of Economic Studies, 19, 28–35.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Larue, B., & Gervais, J.-P. (2002). Welfare-maximizing and revenue-maximizing tariffs with a few domestic firms. Canadian Journal of Economics, 35, 786–804.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Niskanen, W. A. (1971). Bureaucracy and representative government. Chicago: Aldine Atherton.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vickers, J. (1985). Delegation and the theory of the firm. Economic Journal, Supplement 95, 138–147.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgement

This work was supported by Grants-in-Aid for Scientific Research (nos. 26380340, 5K03492, 17K03734, and 17K03735). We thank an anonymous reviewer for helpful comments. All remaining errors are ours.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Masayuki Hayashibara .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendices

Appendices

1.1 Appendix 10.1: Proof of Lemma 10.2

First, we compare the subsidy rate in the four cases . We compare sWR with sWW, i.e.,

$$ {s}^{WR}-{s}^{WW}=\left(1-\frac{2c}{3}\right)-\left(1-\frac{c}{2}\right)<0. $$

Next, the comparison between sPW and sWR yields

$$ {s}^{PW}-{s}^{WR}\propto 6\left(2-c\right)-13\left(3-2c\right)=20c-27<0. $$

Furthermore, by comparing sPR with sWR, we obtain

$$ {s}^{PR}-{s}^{WR}\propto 3\left(5-2c\right)-17\left(3-2c\right)=28c-36<0. $$

Subtracting sPW from sPR yields

$$ {s}^{PR}-{s}^{PW}\propto 13\left(5-2c\right)-34\left(2-c\right)=8c-3, $$

which means that if 0 < c < 3/8, then sPR < sPW; if 3/8 ≤ c < 1, then sPR ≥ sPW.

Secondly, we compare the tariff rate among the four cases. Comparing tWR with tRW yields

$$ {t}^{WR}-{t}^{PW}\propto 26c-3\left(3+5c\right)=11c-9, $$

which means that if c < 9/11, then tWR < tPW; if 9/11 ≤ c < 1, then tWR ≥ tPW.

Next, we compare tWR with tPR:

$$ {t}^{WR}-{t}^{PR}\propto 34c-9\left(1+3c\right)=7c-9<0. $$

Finally, by subtracting tPR from tPW, we obtain

$$ {t}^{PR}-{t}^{PW}\propto 39\left(1+3c\right)-17\left(3+5c\right)=8c-3, $$

which means that if 0 < c < 3/8, then tPR < tPW; if 3/8 ≤ c < 1, then tPR ≥ tPW. Note that tWW < tWR. Thus, the statements of Lemma 10.2 hold.

1.2 Appendix 10.2: Proof of Proposition 10.3

Suppose that the tariff department selects strategy R as its objective . Subtracting PSWR from PSPR yields

$$ {\displaystyle \begin{array}{c}{PS}^{PR}-{PS}^{WR}\propto 162{\left(5-2c\right)}^2-289c\left(9-5c\right)\\ {}=2093{c}^2-5841c+4050\\ {}=\left(7c-9\right)\left(299c-450\right)>0.\end{array}} $$

Suppose that the tariff department selects strategy W as its objective. Then, PSPW > PSWW = 0 clearly. Therefore, strategy P is a dominant strategy for the subsidy department.

Suppose that the subsidy department selects strategy P. Comparing TRPR with TRPW yields

$$ {\displaystyle \begin{array}{c}{TR}^{PR}-{TR}^{PW}\propto 1014{\left(1+3\mathrm{c}\right)}^2-289\left(3+5c\right)\left(1+6c\right)\\ {}=456{c}^2-563c+147\\ {}=\left(8c-3\right)\left(57c-49\right),\end{array}} $$

which means that if 0 < c < 3/8 or if 49/57 ≤ c < 1, then TRPR ≥ TRPW; if 3/8 ≤ c < 49/57, then TRPR < TRPW. Thus, we have proven Proposition 10.3.

1.3 Appendix 10.3: Proof of Lemma 10.3

First, we compare WWR with WWW:

$$ {W}^{WR}-{W}^{WW}\propto 4\left(13{c}^2+27\right)-54\left({c}^2+2\right)=-2{c}^2<0. $$

Secondly, by comparing WPW with WWR, we obtain

$$ {\displaystyle \begin{array}{c}{W}^{PW}-{W}^{WR}\propto 27\left(80{c}^2+18c+151\right)-169\left(13{c}^2+27\right)\\ {}=-37{c}^2+486\left(c-1\right)<0.\end{array}} $$

Thirdly, comparing WPR with WWR yields

$$ {\displaystyle \begin{array}{c}{W}^{PR}-{W}^{WR}\propto 216\left(16{c}^2+5c+32\right)-289\left(13{c}^2+27\right)\\ {}=-301{c}^2+1080c-891\equiv h(c).\end{array}} $$

Since h'(c) =  − 602c + 1080 &gt; 0 for c ∈ (0, 1) and h(1) =  − 112 < 0, h(c) < 0 for c ∈ (0, 1). This means that WPR < WWR. Finally, we compare WPR with WPW:

$$ {\displaystyle \begin{array}{c}{W}^{PR}-{W}^{PW}\propto 1352\left(16{c}^2+5c+32\right)-289\left(80{c}^2+18c+151\right)\\ {}=-1488{c}^2+1558c-375=-\left(8c-3\right)\left(186c-125\right)\end{array}} $$

which means that if 0 < c < 3/8 or if 125/186 < c < 1, then WPR < WPW; if 3/8 ≤ c ≤ 125/186, then WPR ≥ WPW. Thus, we have proven Lemma 10.3.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2018 Springer Nature Singapore Pte Ltd.

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Hayashibara, M., Ohkawa, T., Nomura, R., Okamura, M. (2018). On the Incentive for a Self-Interested Policymaker to Mimic the Behavior of a Social-Welfare Maximizer. In: Tran-Nam, B., Tawada, M., Okawa, M. (eds) Recent Developments in Normative Trade Theory and Welfare Economics. New Frontiers in Regional Science: Asian Perspectives, vol 26. Springer, Singapore. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-10-8615-1_10

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics