Skip to main content

Economic Evaluation of Japanese Attorney Fees

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Applied Approaches to Societal Institutions and Economics

Part of the book series: New Frontiers in Regional Science: Asian Perspectives ((NFRSASIPER,volume 18))

  • 364 Accesses

Abstract

The Japanese judicial system does not differ greatly from those of most other civil law countries (Ota, Am J Comp Law 49:561–583, 2001). Especially in terms of allocating litigation costs between plaintiffs and defendants, Japanese rules of cost allocation in litigation resemble the American rules. The American rules hold that each party is responsible for paying their own attorney fees. In contrast, there is an allocation rule of costs between a client and one’s own attorney can be used. That is mainly a contingent fee contractual arrangement, which is very common in the United States, especially for tort litigation. Under a contingent fee, a client is charged for an attorney’s services only if the lawsuit is successful. That is, a client pays a percentage (usually one-third) of the recovery to the attorney (See Miceli (The economic approach to law. Stanford University Press, Stanford, 2004) and Kakalik and Pace (Costs and compensation paid in tort litigation. Rand Institute for Civil Justice, Santa Monica, 1986) reported a US survey showing that 96% of individual plaintiff attorneys in tort litigation paid their attorneys on a contingency basis, but almost all the defendants’ attorneys were paid according to an hourly rate.). However, as for allocating costs between a defendant and an attorney, the Japanese legal system differs from the American system. It is a reverse contingent fee. The reverse contingent fee is one by which a defense attorney’s compensation depends in part on how much money his attorney saves the defendant: the lower the judgment given, the higher the attorney’s fee (Garner, Black’s law dictionary, 9th edn. West Group, St. Paul, 2009). Actually, reverse contingent fees are prohibited or substantially restricted in many other common law and civil law legal systems (Rubinfeld and Scotchmer, Contingent fees. In: Newman P (ed) The new Palgrave dictionary of economics and the law, vol 1. Stockton Press, New York, 1998, pp 415–420). In Japan, however, deregulation of attorney’s fees began in 2004 by the Judicial Reform of Japan. Therefore, reverse contingent fees are not banned under the Japanese legal system (Japan Federation of Bar Association, Rules concerning Attorney’s fees. JFBA Official Web Page, 2008, in English).

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    See Miceli (2004) and Kakalik and Pace (1986) reported a US survey showing that 96% of individual plaintiff attorneys in tort litigation paid their attorneys on a contingency basis, but almost all the defendants’ attorneys were paid according to an hourly rate.

  2. 2.

    See Tullock (1975, 1980), Parisi (2002), and Baik (2008).

  3. 3.

    We assume that the defendant pays V because he has no defense if defendant does not hire an attorney and assume payment pV if he hires an attorney.

  4. 4.

    The second-order condition can be confirmed easily.

References

  • Baik, K.H. 2008. Attorneys’ compensation in litigation with bilateral delegation. Review of Law and Economics 4(1):259–289.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Garner, B. (ed.). 2009. Black’s law dictionary. 9th ed. St. Paul: West Group.

    Google Scholar 

  • Japan Federation of Bar Association. (2008) Rules concerning Attorney’s fees, JFBA Official Web Page (In English).

    Google Scholar 

  • Kakalik, J.S., and N. Pace. 1986. Costs and compensation paid in tort litigation. Santa Monica: Rand Institute for Civil Justice.

    Google Scholar 

  • Miceli, J.T. 2004. The economic approach to law. Stanford: Stanford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ota, S. 2001. Reform of civil procedure in Japan. The American Journal of Comparative Law 49:561–583.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Parisi, F. 2002. Rent-seeking through litigation: Adversarial and inquisitorial systems compared. International Review of Law and Economics 22(2):193–216.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rubinfeld, D.L., and S. Scotchmer. 1998. Contingent fees. In The new Palgrave dictionary of economics and the law, ed. P. Newman, vol. 1, 415–420. New York: Stockton Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. 1975. On the efficient organization of trials. Kyklas 28:745–762.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. 1980. Trials on trials. New York: Columbia University Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Yasuhiro Ikeda .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2017 Springer Nature Singapore Pte Ltd.

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Ikeda, Y. (2017). Economic Evaluation of Japanese Attorney Fees. In: Naito, T., Lee, W., Ouchida, Y. (eds) Applied Approaches to Societal Institutions and Economics. New Frontiers in Regional Science: Asian Perspectives, vol 18. Springer, Singapore. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-10-5663-5_4

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-10-5663-5_4

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Singapore

  • Print ISBN: 978-981-10-5662-8

  • Online ISBN: 978-981-10-5663-5

  • eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics