Skip to main content

Subjective Rational Compliance Calculation and Deterrence: Theory and Empirical Evidence

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Pesticide Law and Compliance Decision Making
  • 188 Accesses

Abstract

The illegal use of pesticides in China has increasingly produced adverse effects on human health and environmental sustainability.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

eBook
USD 16.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Simpson and Rorie (2012) reviewed the most recent studies that critically look at the traditional economic rational choice model to crime and punishment, and collectively called them “modified versions of the perspective”. They concluded that these studies mainly focus on the limits on rationality (e.g., access to information, individual differences), the non-material costs and benefits of violation behavior, and the differences of the information needed and utilized by offenders among different types of offence, etc.

  2. 2.

    Here “decentered” deterrence refers to a strand of study in regulatory theory that considers regulation no longer as the sole affair of the state but as a “de-centered” matter in which multiple state and non-state actors play regulatory roles including these of implementing the law (Van Rooij 2013).

  3. 3.

    That is, (Cb-Cc)—(Vb-Vc), which indicates benefits of compliance minus costs of compliance subtracting benefits of violation minus costs of violation.

  4. 4.

    In order to solve the misunderstanding problem, operational costs and benefits in relation to compliance with rules on the use of types of pesticides are operationalized separately to the price and effectiveness of pesticides.

  5. 5.

    In order to solve the sensitivity problem, several strategies were employed, e.g., vegetable farmers were not directly asked to compare the costs and benefits of compliance and violation but rather asked to compare the costs and benefits of their own pesticide behaviors (compliant or noncompliant) and these of the alternative (noncompliant or compliant) pesticide behaviors (a specific example is provided in Part C of the Appendix).

  6. 6.

    They are mainly Beccaria and Bentham. Both of them took the position that human beings behave in accordance with the principle of greatest happiness, that is, they pursue the greatest pleasure or happiness and reduce pain or suffering. This was later developed further by Bentham (1988) into full-scale utilitarianism. Based on the principle of utility, potential offenders can be deterred by increasing sanctions and thus more compliance occurs.

  7. 7.

    William and Hawkins (1986), for instance, summarized relevant findings and argued that there is little evidence for the association between perceived sanction severity and self-reported involvement in crime.

  8. 8.

    Here the “third parties” refer to all non-state actors involved in deterrence.

  9. 9.

    “Acquaintance society” was primarily proposed by Fei Xiaotong, Xiangtu Zhongguo. Shanghai: Guancha, 1948 (translated as From the Soil: The Foundations of Chinese Society, Univ. of California Press, 1992). Fei was a pioneering Chinese researcher and professor of sociology and anthropology. Acquaintance society generally refers to interpersonal relationships.

  10. 10.

    Guanxi describes the basic dynamic in personalized networks of influence and is a central idea in Chinese society (from Wikipedia).

  11. 11.

    Unlike most objective deterrence literature that examines sanction severity, this study examines the regulated actors’ sanction impact, as it is more adaptive to the subjective approach.

References

  • Becker, Crime. 1968. Punishment: An economic approach. Journal of Political Economy 169(177): 183–184.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bentham, Jeremy. 1988. The principles of morals and legislation. 1789. Amherst, NY: Prometheus Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Black, Donald. 2000. Dreams of pure sociology. Sociological Theory 18(3): 343–367.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Black, J. 2003. Enrolling actors in regulatory systems: Examples from UK financial services regulation spring. Public Law 2003: 63–91.

    Google Scholar 

  • Braithwaite, John., and Toni Makkai. 1991. Testing an expected utility model of corporate deterrence. Law and Society Review 7–40.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chiricos, Theodore G., and Gordon P. Waldo. 1970. Punishment and crime: An examination of some empirical evidence. Social Problems 200–217.

    Google Scholar 

  • Decker, Scott, Richard Wright, and Robert Logie. 1993. Perceptual deterrence among active residential burglars: A research note. Criminology 31(1): 135–147.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ehrlich, Isaac. 1972. Deterrent effect of criminal law enforcement. The Journal of Legal Studies 1: 259–276.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ehrlich, Isaac. 1975. The deterrent effect of capital punishment: A question of life and death. The American Economic Review 65(3): 397–417.

    Google Scholar 

  • Erickson, Maynard L., and Jack P. Gibbs. 1978. Objective and perceptual properties of legal punishment and the deterrence doctrine. Social Problems 253–264.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gibbs, Jack P. 1975. Crime, Punishment, and Deterrence. New York: Elsevier.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grabosky, Peter N. 1995. Using non-governmental resources to foster regulatory compliance. Governance 8(4):527–550.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grasmick, Harold G., and Donald E. Green. 1980. Legal punishment, social disapproval and internalization as inhibitors of illegal behavior. The Journal of Criminal Law and Criminology (1973) 71(3): 325–335.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gray, Wayne B., and John T. Scholz. 1991. Analyzing the equity and efficiency of OSHA enforcement. Law & Policy 13(3): 185–214.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gray, Wayne B., and Ronald J. Shadbegian. 2005. When and why do plants comply? Paper mills in the 1980s. Law & Policy 27(2): 238–261.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grasmick, Harold G., and George J. Bryjak. 1980. The deterrent effect of perceived severity of punishment. Social Forces 59(2): 471–491.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greenberg, David F. 1981. Methodological issues in survey research on the inhibition of crime. The Journal of Criminal Law and Criminology 72(3): 1094–1101.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gunningham, Neil, Peter Grabosky and Darren Sinclair. 1998. Smart regulation: Designing environmental policy (Oxford Socio-Legal Studies) (POD).

    Google Scholar 

  • Gunningham, Neil, and Darren Sinclair. 1999. Regulatory pluralism: Designing policy mixes for environmental protection. Law & Policy 21(1): 49–76.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gunningham, Dorothy Thornton, R.A Kagan and D. Thornton. 2003. Shades of green: Business. In Regulation and Environment (Palo Alto, CA: Stanford University Press).

    Google Scholar 

  • Gunningham, Dorothy Thornton, and Robert A. Kagan. 2005. Motivating management: Corporate compliance in environmental protection. Law & Policy 27(2): 289–316.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hawkins, Keith. 1984. Environment and enforcement: Regulation and the social definition of pollution.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hutter, Bridget M. 1989. Variations in regulatory enforcement styles. Law & Policy 11(2): 153–174.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hutter, Bridget M. 2011. Managing Food Safety and Hygiene: Governance and Regulation as Risk Management. Massachusetts: Edward Elgar Pub.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Jacobs, Bruce A. 2010. Deterrence and deterrability. Criminology 48(2): 417–441.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kagan, R.A., and J.T. Scholz. 1984. The criminology of the corporation and regulatory enforcement strategies. Enforcing Regulation 67: 69–74.

    Google Scholar 

  • Klepper, Steven, and Daniel Nagin. 1989a. Tax compliance and perceptions of the risks of detection and criminal prosecution. Law and Society Review 209–240.

    Google Scholar 

  • Klepper, Steven and Daniel Nagin. 1989b. The deterrent effect of perceived certainty and severity of punishment revisited. Criminology 27(4): 721–746.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li, Weiming. and He Yimin. 2011. Qianghua Nongye Guanli, Baozheng Nongchanpin Zhiliang Anquan (Enhancing pesticide supervision and administration, and ensuring quality and safety of agricultural products). Nongyao Kexue yu Guanli (Pesticide Science and Administration) 32(11).

    Google Scholar 

  • Lo, Carlos W.H., and Gerald E. Fryxell. 2003. Enforcement styles among environmental protection officials in China. Journal of Public Policy 23(1): 81–115.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • May, Peter J., and Søren Winter. 1999. Regulatory enforcement and compliance: Examining danish agro-environmental policy. Journal of Policy Analysis and Management 18(4): 625–651.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • May, P.J. 2005. Compliance motivations: Perspectives of farmers, homebuilders, and marine facilities. Law & Policy 27(2): 317–347.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McAllister, Lesley K. 2010. Dimensions of enforcement style: Factoring in regulatory autonomy and capacity. Law & Policy 32(1): 61–78.

    Google Scholar 

  • McAllister, Lesley K., Benjamin Van Rooij and Robert A. Kagan. 2010. Reorienting regulation: Pollution enforcement in industrializing countries. Law & Policy 32(1): 1–13.

    Google Scholar 

  • Meier, Robert F., and Weldon T. Johnson. 1977. Deterrence as social control: The legal and extralegal production of conformity. American Sociological Review 42(2): 292–304.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mendeloff, John and Wayne B. Gray. 2005. Inside the black box: How do OSHA inspections lead to reductions in workplace injuries? Law & Policy 27(2): 219–237.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nagin, Daniel S., and Raymond Paternoster. 1991. The preventive effects of the perceived risk of arrest: Testing an expanded conception of deterrence. Criminology 29(4): 561–587.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nagin, Daniel S., and Pogarsky Grey. 2001. Integrating celerity, impulsivity, and extralegal sanction threats into a model of general deterrence: Theory and evidence. Criminology 39(4): 865–892.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nielsen, Vibeke Lehmann, and Christine Parker. 2008. To what extent do third parties influence business compliance? Journal of Law and Society 35(3): 309–340.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Parker, Christine and Vibeke Lehmann Nielson. 2012b. 1. Introduction. In Explaining regulatory compliance: Business responses to regulation, pp. 1–33.

    Google Scholar 

  • Paternoster, Raymond. 1987. The deterrent effect of the perceived certainty and severity of punishment: A review of the evidence and issues. Justice Quarterly 4(2): 173–217.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Paternoster, and Sally Simpson. 1993. A rational choice theory of corporate crime. Routine Activity and Rational Choice 5: 37.

    Google Scholar 

  • Paternoster, and Sally Simpson. 1996. Sanction threats and appeals to morality: Testing a rational choice model of corporate crime. Law & Society Review 30(3): 549–584.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Raymond, Paternoster, Linda E. Saltzman, Theodore G. Chiricos, and Gordon P. Waldo. 1982. Perceived risk and deterrence: Methodological artifacts in perceptual deterrence research. Journal of Criminal Law & Criminology 73: 1238.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simpson, Sally S., and Melissa Rorie. 2012. 3. Motivating compliance: Economic and material motives for compliance. In Explaining compliance: Business responses to regulation, edited by Christine Parker and Vibeke Lehman Nielsen, pp. 59–77.

    Google Scholar 

  • Song, Tianjun, et al. 2004. Woguo Nongyao Guanli de Xiangzhuang ji Shexiang (Present situation and tentative plan for national pesticide management). Dangdai Shengtai Nongye (Modern Ecological Agriculture) 1: 120–122.

    Google Scholar 

  • State Environmental Protection General Administration. 2001. Woguo Nongyao Wuran Xiangzhuang Cunzai Wenti ji Jianyi (China’s pesticide pollution and its problems and suggestions). Huanjing Baohu (Environmental Protection) 6: 23–24.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stigler,George J. 1970. The optimum enforcement of laws. Journal of Political Economy 78(3): 526-536.

    Google Scholar 

  • Thornton, Dorothy, Neil Gunningham, and Robert A. Kagan. 2005. General deterrence and corporate environmental behavior. Law & Policy 27(2): 262–288.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tittle, Charles R. 1969. Crime rates and legal sanctions. Social Problems 409–423.

    Google Scholar 

  • Van Rooij, B., and Carlos W-H Lo. 2010. Fragile convergence: Understanding variation in the enforcement of china’s industrial pollution law. Law & Policy 32(1): 14–37.

    Google Scholar 

  • Van Rooij. 2013a. Deterrence without enforcement—dialogues with Chinese lawyers about tax evasion and compliance. A Paper presented on the Third East Asian Law & Society Conference which was organized by the Collaborative Research Network: East Asian Law and Society (EALS) and the SJTU Law and Society Center in Shanghai, March 22–23, 2013.

    Google Scholar 

  • Van Rooij, Benjamin. 2013b. Compliance as process: A micro approach to regulatory implementation. (on file with the author).

    Google Scholar 

  • Wei et al. 2011. Woguo Nongyao Anquan Guanli Xianzhuang、Jiyu he Tiaozhan (The situation, opportunity and development measures of national pesticide safety management). Nongchanpin Zhiliang yu Anquan (Quality and Safety of Agro-Products) 1: 11–14.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williams, Kirk R., and Richard Hawkins. 1986. Perceptual research on general deterrence: A critical review. Law & Society Review 20: 545.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Winter, Soren C., and Peter J. May. 2001. Motivation for compliance with environmental regulations. Journal of Policy Analysis and Management 20(4): 675–698.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Winter, Soren C., and Peter J. May. 2002. Information, interests, and environmental regulation. Journal of Comparative Policy Analysis 4(2): 115–142.

    Google Scholar 

  • Xiaotong, Fei. 1992. From the soil: The foundations of Chinese society. California: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zhao, Jianxin. 2008. Nonghu Anquan Shucai Gongji Juece Jizhi Yanjiu Jiyu Heibei, Shandong He Zhejiang Nongnong De Shizheng (Research on Farmers’ Decision-making mechanism on safe vegetable supply: Empirical study based on vegetable farmers in Hebei, Shandong and Zhejiang). Doctoral Thesis from CNKI (China Knowledge Resource Integrated Database). http://oversea.cnki.net/kns55/default.aspx

  • Zimring, Franklin E., Gordon Hawkins and James Gorenberg. 1973. Deterrence: The legal threat in crime control. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Huiqi Yan .

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2017 Springer Nature Singapore Pte Ltd.

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Yan, H. (2017). Subjective Rational Compliance Calculation and Deterrence: Theory and Empirical Evidence. In: Pesticide Law and Compliance Decision Making. Springer, Singapore. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-10-3917-1_3

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-10-3917-1_3

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Singapore

  • Print ISBN: 978-981-10-3916-4

  • Online ISBN: 978-981-10-3917-1

  • eBook Packages: Law and CriminologyLaw and Criminology (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics