Skip to main content

Does Patent Strategy Shape the Long-Run Supply of Public Knowledge?

Evidence from Human Genetics

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Book cover Innovation and IPRs in China and India

Part of the book series: China-EU Law Series ((CELS,volume 4))

  • 579 Accesses

Abstract

How do firms’ patent strategies, and the landscape of private property rights they collectively produce, influence the long-run production of public knowledge? Management scholars have paid close attention to the ways in which firms benefit from public knowledge—ideas disclosed through open commons institutions—by using it to generate private knowledge, which is protected by private property institutions such as patents (Cockburn and Henderson 1998; Cohen and Levinthal 1990; Fleming and Sorenson 2004; Powell et al. 1996). However, they have paid scant attention to the converse relationship: the impact of private knowledge on public knowledge production. Instead, legal and policy analyses dominate the study of this relationship (Heller 2008; Heller and Eisenberg 1998; Lessig 2004). This situation speaks to the importance of a management perspective linking policy and legal studies with organizational theory and strategy that can initiate a rich agenda examining the interaction between firm strategy and the institutional foundations of knowledge work.

Republished with permission of Academy of Management, from: Does patent strategy shape the long-run supply of public knowledge? Evidence from human genetics, Kenneth G. Huang and Fiona E. Murray, 52, 6, 2009; permission conveyed through Copyright Clearance Center, Inc.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 79.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 99.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 139.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    The US Supreme Court in its latest unanimous decision (on June 13, 2013) on the patentability on gene, namely, Association for Molecular Pathology vs. Myriad Genetics, Inc., ruled that naturally isolated DNA is not patentable but that synthetic DNA, such as the cDNA for the BRCA1 and BRCA2 genes, is patentable. (See, e.g., http://scopeblog.stanford.edu/2013/06/13/supreme-court-rules-on-myriads-gene-patenting-case/#sthash.9HwWEE9U.dpuf)

  2. 2.

    At least three measures have been used to capture the relationship between public and private knowledge streams: the number of publications cited in patents, or “science linkage” (Narin et al. 1997; Tijssen 2002); the patent and publication portfolios of firms (Gittelman and Kogut 2003; Lim 2000); and coauthorship and copatenting networks (Owen-Smith and Powell 2003; Powell et al. 1996; Zucker et al. 1998).

  3. 3.

    Exceptions to the “refusal to license” arise when the federal government exercises “march-in” rights (insisting on licensing ideas they funded), and when antitrust is binding (Lewis and Yao 1995; MacKie-Mason 2002).

  4. 4.

    We hold degrees in biomedical engineering and applied chemistry. In almost all the cases, the patent-paper pair assignment was unambiguous.

  5. 5.

    These observable characteristics include patent application and grant year, patent grant lag, number of national classes, type of national classes, number of claims, number of inventors, number of patentees, number of cited patent references, number of citing patent references, number of nonpatents cited, and several constructed patent measures based on Trajtenberg et al. (1997).

  6. 6.

    Number of inventors, classes, and nonpatents cited differ slightly: 2.6–3.3, 6.2–6.3, and 479–459 in the sample versus population, respectively. The actual differences in magnitude in all three cases are trivial.

  7. 7.

    First published in Futreal et al. (2004), this census summarizes more than two decades of searching. This census is updated on http://www.sanger.ac.uk/genetics/CGP/Census/.

  8. 8.

    As an additional test, we used two other variations of the citation data: (1) excluding organizational self-citations (defined as citations of papers written by any author from the same organization as the author of the focal paper) and (2) including author and organization self-citations. In both cases, the results remain essentially unchanged: the directions of the coefficients are similar and the differences in their magnitudes are very small.

  9. 9.

    We analyzed both the impact of increase in patent scope and the impact of increase in scope from the mean (or positive deviation). The regression results are similar for both procedures. Similarly, we analyzed both the impact of increases in patent strength and the impact of increases in strength from the mean (or positive deviation), again obtaining similar results with both procedures. We report the latter in Table 6.

  10. 10.

    As genes claimed by more than 10 patents (i.e., 11–20 patents) represent only about 1.7% of the total observations in our sample (or 0.02, rounded up to two decimal places), we have aggregated them into one category.

  11. 11.

    Again, we analyzed both the impact of increases in fragmentation and the impact of increase in fragmentation from the mean fragmentation (or positive deviation). The regression results are similar for both procedures. We report the latter in Table 7.

  12. 12.

    In the likelihood-ratio test, H1: E(y it ) < var(y it ) is supported.

  13. 13.

    Note also that the standard errors from the Poisson regression model can be biased downward, resulting in spuriously large z-values (Cameron and Trivedi 1986). The z-tests may overestimate the significance of the variables in the case of overdispersion in the data (Long 1997). The results of the Hausman (1978) test also supported the use of the fixed effects negative binomial regression model.

  14. 14.

    In our data, the goodness-of-fit test allowed us to reject the Poisson distribution assumption and indicated a zero-inflated distribution, showing further support for the negative binomial regression model.

  15. 15.

    To check and insulate our results against any possibility that the interaction effects in a nonlinear model were not the same as their cross-partial derivatives, we performed an additional regression similar to the one described in model 3 in Table 6 on split samples for each model in Table 7 (except model 5). For example, in model 1, Table 7, we performed the regression in the subsample with public assignee only (7718 observations) and then another regression on the subsample with no public assignees only (5112 observations). We repeated this procedure for the remaining models. These split-sample regressions yielded results that were consistent with those shown in Table 7 and equally robust, and our findings were unchanged across the models.

  16. 16.

    In our analysis of the impact of increase in fragmentation using the measure presented in Eq. 1, the regression result (available upon request) also showed a 7% significant decrease as fragmentation increased. Thus, our findings are consistent.

  17. 17.

    As an additional check against potential collinearity among the fixed effects, we also performed the fully interacted specification on regression models 3–6 in Table 6 and models 1–8 in Table 7. That is, instead of paper fixed effects, paper age fixed effects, and citation year fixed effects, we included paper fixed effects and the full set of paper year–paper age interaction dummies. Results were consistent with those shown in Tables 6 and 7 and equally robust; the coefficients have similar directions and almost identical magnitudes (results available upon request).

References

  • Aghion P, Dewatripont M, Stein J (2005) Academic freedom, private-sector focus and the process of innovation. Working paper no. 11542, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Almeida P, Dokko G, Rosenkopf L (2003) Startup size and the mechanisms of external learning: increasing opportunity and decreasing ability? Res Policy 32:301–315

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andrews EL (1991) U.S. seeks patent on genetic codes, setting off furor. New York Times, October 21

    Google Scholar 

  • Bertrand M, Duflo E, Mullainathan S (2004) How much should we trust difference-in-differences estimates. Q J Econ 119:249–275

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blumenthal D (1997) Withholding research results in academic life science: evidence from a national survey of faculty. J Am Med Assoc 277:1224–1228

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bush V (1945) Science: the endless frontier. United States Government Printing Office, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Cameron CA, Trivedi PK (1986) Econometric models based on count data: comparisons and applications of some estimators and tests. J Appl Econ 1:29–54

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cameron CA, Trivedi PK (1998) Regression analysis of count data. Cambridge University Press, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Campbell EG, Clarridge BR, Gokhale M, Birenbaum L, Hilgartner S, Holtzman NA, Blumenthal D (2002) Data withholding in academic genetics: evidence from a national survey. J Am Med Assoc 287:473–479

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cho MK, Illangasekare S, Weaver MA, Leonard DGB, Merz JF (2003) Effects of patents and licenses on the provision of clinical genetic testing services. J Mol Diagn 5(1):3–8

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cockburn I, Henderson R (1998) Absorptive capacity, coauthoring behavior, and the organization of research in drug discovery. J Ind Econ 46(2):157–182

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cohen W, Levinthal D (1990) Absorptive capacity: a new perspective on learning and innovation. Adm Sci Q 35:128–152

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Colyvas JA, Powell WW (2006) Roads to institutionalization: the remaking of boundaries between public and private science. In: Kramer RM, Staw BM (eds) Research in organizational behavior, vol 21. JAI Press, Greenwich, pp 305–353

    Google Scholar 

  • Crichton M (2006) Next. Harper Collins, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Dasgupta P, David PA (1994) Towards a new economics of science. Res Policy 23:487–521

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • de Solla Price DJ (1965) Networks of scientific papers. Science 149:510–515

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dreyfuss R (2004) Protecting the public domain of science: has the time for an experimental use defense arrived? Ariz Law Rev 46:457–472

    Google Scholar 

  • Ducor P (2000) Intellectual property: coauthorship and coinventorship. Science 289:873–875

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eisenberg R (1996) Public research and private development: patents and technology transfer in government-sponsored research. Virginia Law Rev 82:1663–1727

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fauchart E, von Hippel E (2008) Norms-Based intellectual property systems: the case of French chefs. Organ Sci 19(2):187–201

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ferber MA (1988) Citations and networking. Gend Soc 2(1):82–89

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fleming L, Sorenson O (2004) Science as a map in technological search. Strateg Manag J 25:909–928

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Furman J, Stern S (2006) Climbing atop the shoulders of giants: the impact of institutions on cumulative research, Working paper. National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Futreal PA, Coin L, Marshall M, Down T, Hubbard T, Wooster R, Rahman N, Stratton MR (2004) A census of human cancer genes. Nat Rev Cancer 4:177–183

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gans J, Stern S (2000) Incumbency and R&D incentives: licensing the gale of creative destruction. J Econ Manag Strateg 8:484–511

    Google Scholar 

  • Gans J, Stern S (2003) The product market and the market for “ideas”: commercialization strategies for technology entrepreneurs. Res Policy 32:333–350

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gans J, Hsu D, Stern S (2008a) The impact of uncertain intellectual property rights on the market for ideas: evidence from patent grant delays. Manag Sci 54:982–997

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gans J, Murray F, Stern S (2008b) Patents, papers and secrecy: scientific disclosure as a negotiation between scientists and those who fund them. Working paper, Massachusetts Institute of Technology Sloan School of Management, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Garfield E (1955) Citation indexes for science: a new dimension in documentation through association of ideas. Science 122:108–111

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gittelman M, Kogut B (2003) Does good science lead to valuable knowledge? Biotechnology firms and the evolutionary logic of citation patterns. Manag Sci 49:366–382

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greenfield DL (2006) Greenberg v. Miami children’s hospital: unjust enrichment and the patenting of human genetic material. Ann Health Law 15(2):213–249

    Google Scholar 

  • Hagström WO (1965) The scientific community. Basic Books, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Hall BH, Jaffe AB, Trajtenberg M (2001) The NBER patent citation data file: lessons, insights and methodological tools. Working paper no. 8498, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA. Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=285618

  • Hansen MT (1999) The search-transfer problem: the role of weak ties in sharing knowledge across organization subunits. Adm Sci Q 44:82–111

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harhoff D, Reitzig M (2004) Determinants of opposition against EPO patent grants: the case of biotechnology and pharmaceuticals. Int J Ind Organ 22:443–480

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hausman JA (1978) Specification tests in econometrics. Econometrica 46:1251–1271

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hausman JA, Hall BH, Griliches Z (1984) Econometric models for count data with an application to the patents-R&D relationship. Econometrica 52:909–938

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heller MA (2008) Gridlock economy: how too much ownership wrecks markets, stops innovation and costs lives. Basic Books, Philadelphia

    Google Scholar 

  • Heller MA, Eisenberg RS (1998) Can patents deter innovation? The anti-commons in biomedical research. Science 280:698–701

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henderson R, Cockburn I (1994) Measuring competence? Exploring firm effects in pharmaceutical research. Strateg Manag J 15:63–84

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henry RM, Cho MK, Weaver MA, Merz JF (2002) DNA patenting and licensing. Science 297:1279

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hitt M (2005) Management theory and research: potential contributions to public policy and public organizations. Acad Manag J 48:963–966

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hoetker G, Agarwal R (2007) Death hurts but isn’t fatal: the postexit diffusion of knowledge created by innovative companies. Acad Manag J 50:446–467

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holman CM (2007) The impact of human gene patents on innovation and access: a survey of human gene patent litigation.. Working paper IPSC, http://www.law.depaul.edu/institutes_centers/ciplit/ipsc/paper/Chris_HolmanPaper.pdf

    Google Scholar 

  • Holman MA, Munzer SR (2000) Intellectual property rights in genes and gene fragments: a registration solution for expressed sequence tags. Iowa Law Rev 85:735–848

    Google Scholar 

  • Huang KG (2006) Innovation in the life sciences: the impact of intellectual property rights on scientific knowledge diffusion, accumulation and utilization. Unpublished doctoral dissertation, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Huang KG (2016) Uncertain intellectual property conditions and knowledge appropriation strategies: evidence from the genomics industry. Ind Corp Change (forthcoming)

    Google Scholar 

  • Huang KG, Ertug G (2014) Mobility, retention and productivity of genomics scientists in the U.S. Nat Biotechnol 32(9):953–958

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huang KJ, Murray F (2010) Entrepreneurial experiments in science policy: analyzing the Human Genome Project. Res Policy 39(5):567–582

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jensen K, Murray F (2005) The intellectual property landscape of the human genome. Science 310:239–240

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klevorick A, Levin R, Nelson R, Winter S (1995) On the sources and significance of inter-industry differences in technological opportunities. Res Policy 24:185–205

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Knorr-Cetina K (1999) Epistemic cultures: how sciences make knowledge. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Kogut B, Almeida P (1999) Localization of knowledge and the mobility of engineers in regional networks. Manag Sci 45:905–917

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kogut B, Zander U (1992) Knowledge of the firm, combinative capabilities, and the replication of technology. Organ Sci 3:383–397

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kohler RE (1994) Lords of the fly: “Drosophila” genetics and the experimental life. University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Krimsky S (2003) Science in the private interest. Rowman & Littlefield Publishing Group, Lanham

    Google Scholar 

  • Lanjouw JO, Schankerman MA (2001) Enforcing intellectual property rights, Discussion paper no. 3093. Center for Economic and Policy Research, Washington, DC

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Latour B, Woolgar S (1979) Laboratory life: the construction of scientific facts. Sage, Beverly Hills

    Google Scholar 

  • Lemley MA, Shapiro C (2005) Probabilistic patents. J Econ Perspect 19(2):75–98

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lerner J (1994) The importance of patent scope: an empirical analysis. RAND J Econ 25:319–333

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lessig L (2004) Free culture: how big media uses technology and the law to lock down culture and control creativity. Penguin Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Lewis TR, Yao DA (1995) Some reflections on the antitrust treatment of intellectual property. Antitrust Law J 63:603–619

    Google Scholar 

  • Lim K (2000) Basic research, applied research, and innovation in the semiconductor and pharmaceutical industries. Unpublished doctoral dissertation, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Long SJ (1997) Count outcomes: regression models for counts. In: Regression models for categorical and limited dependent variables. Sage, Thousand Oaks, pp 217–250

    Google Scholar 

  • MacKie-Mason JK (2002) What to do about unilateral refusals to license? Paper submitted as testimony to the FTC-DOJ hearings, “Competition and Intellectual Property Law and Policy in the Knowledge-Based Economy,” available at http://www.ftc.gov/opp/intellect/detailsandparticipants.htm#May%201

  • Mazzoleni R, Nelson RR (1998) Economic theories about the benefits and costs of patents. J Econ Issues 32:1031–1052

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Merton RK (1973) The normative structure of science. In: Storer NW (ed) The sociology of science: theoretical and empirical investigations. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, pp 267–280

    Google Scholar 

  • Merz JF (1999) Disease gene patents: overcoming unethical constraints on clinical laboratory medicine. Clin Chem 45:324–330

    Google Scholar 

  • Meyer M (2000) Does science push technology? Patents citing scientific literature. Res Policy 29:409–434

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Murray F (2002) Innovation as co-evolution of scientific and technological networks: exploring tissue engineering. Res Policy 31:1389–1403

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Murray F (2007) The stem cell market: patents and the pursuit of scientific progress. N Engl J Med 356:2341–2343

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Murray F (2008) The oncomouse that roared: hybrid exchange strategies as a source of productive tension at the boundary of overlapping institutions. Working paper, Massachusetts Institute of Technology Sloan School of Management, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Murray F, O’Mahony S (2007) Exploring the foundations of cumulative innovation: implications for organization science. Organ Sci 18:1006–1021

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Murray F, Stern S (2007) Do formal intellectual property rights hinder the free flow of scientific knowledge? An empirical test of the anti-commons hypothesis. J Econ Behav Organ 63:648–687

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Murray F, Stern S (2008) Learning to live with patents: assessing the dynamic adaptation to the law by the scientific community. Working paper, Massachusetts Institute of Technology Sloan School of Management, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Murray F, Aghion P, Dewatripont M, Kolev J, Stern S (2008) Of mice and growth: the effects of openness on follow-on research. Working paper, Massachusetts Institute of Technology Sloan School of Management, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Narin F, Hamilton K, Olivastro D (1997) The increasing linkage between U.S. technology and public science. Res Policy 26:317–330

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nash M (2000) Who owns the genome? CNN, April 10. http://www.cgi.cnn.com/ALLPOLITICS/time/2000/04/10/genome.html

  • Nelson RR (1959) The simple economics of basic scientific research. J Polit Econ 67:297–306

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nomaler Ö, Verspagen B (2007) Knowledge flows, patent citations and the impact of science on technology. Working paper 2007–022, UNU-MERIT

    Google Scholar 

  • Orsi F, Coriat B (2005) Are “strong patents” beneficial to innovative activities? Lessons from the genetic testing for breast cancer controversies. Ind Corp Chang 14:1205–1221

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Owen-Smith J, Powell W (2003) The expanding role of university patenting in the life sciences: assessing the importance of experience and connectivity. Res Policy 32:1695–1711

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Posner RA (2000) An economic analysis of the use of citations in the law. Am Law Econ Rev 2:381–406

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Powell W, Koput K, Smith-Doerr L (1996) Interorganizational collaboration and the locus of innovation: networks of learning in biotechnology. Adm Sci Q 41:116–145

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Resnik D (1998a) Conflicts of interest in science. Perspect Sci 6:381–408

    Google Scholar 

  • Resnik D (1998b) Industry-sponsored research: secrecy versus corporate responsibility. Bus Soc Rev 99(1):31–35

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Romer PM (1994) The origins of endogenous growth. J Econ Perspect 8(1):3–22

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rosenberg N (1974) Science, invention and economic growth. Econ J 84:90–108

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rysman M, Simcoe TS (2008) Patents and the performance of voluntary standard setting organizations. Manag Sci 54:1920–1934

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sampat BN (2005) Do academic genomic patents curtail downstream research? Working paper, Mailman School of Public Health, Columbia University, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Scotchmer S (1991) Standing on the shoulders of giants: cumulative research and the patent law. J Econ Perspect 5(5):29–41

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shapiro C (2001) Navigating the patent thicket: cross licenses, patent pools, and standard-setting. In: Jaffe AB, Lerner J, Stern S (eds) Innovation policy and the economy, vol 1. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA, pp 119–150

    Google Scholar 

  • Shockley W (1949) The theory of P-N junctions in semiconductors and P-N junction transistors. Bell Syst Tech J 28:435–489

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Somaya D (2003) Strategic determinants of decisions not to settle patent litigation. Strateg Manag J 24:17–38

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stern S (2004) Do scientists pay to be scientists? Manag Sci 50:835–853

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stigler G, Friedland C (1975) The citation patterns of doctorates in economics. J Polit Econ 83:477–507

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thursby J, Thursby M (2002) Who is selling the ivory tower? Sources of growth in university licensing. Manag Sci 48:90–104

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tijssen RJW (2002) Science dependence of technologies: evidence from inventions and their inventors. Res Policy 31:509–526

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Trajtenberg M, Henderson R, Jaffe AB (1997) University vs. corporate patents: a window on the basicness of invention. Econ Innov New Technol 5(1):19–50

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • von Hippel E, von Krogh G (2006) Free revealing and the private-collective model for innovation incentives. R&D Manag 36:295–306

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Walsh JP, Arora A, Cohen WM (2003) Patenting and licensing of research tools and biomedical innovation. In: Merrill S, Levin R, Meyers M (eds) Innovation in a knowledge-based economy. National Academies Press, Washington, DC, pp 285–340

    Google Scholar 

  • Walsh JP, Cho C, Cohen WM (2005) View from the bench: patents and material transfers. Science 309:2002–2003

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weitzman M (1974) Free access vs. private ownership as alternative systems for managing common property. J Econ Theory 8:225–234

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ziedonis RH (2004) Don’t fence me in: fragmented markets for technology and the patent acquisition strategies of firms. Manag Sci 50:804–820

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zucker L, Darby M, Brewer M (1998) Intellectual human capital and the birth of U.S. biotechnology enterprise. Am Econ Rev 88:290–306

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Kenneth Guang-Lih Huang .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendix: Key Variable Definitions

Appendix: Key Variable Definitions

Citation year characteristics

Name

Definition

Source

Annual cite

Number of citations made by later papers to the (focal) paper previously published in a given year

ISI

Total cite

Total number of citations accruing to a paper over its lifetime

ISI

Citation year

The year in which the forward citation is received

ISI

Paper age

Age of paper when a citation is made

ISI

Paper characteristics

Paper year

Year when paper is published

ISI

Number of authors

Number of authors appearing on the paper

ISI

Number of addresses

Number of unique addresses appearing on paper

ISI

US address

Binary variable (1/0) denoting at least one US address

ISI

Public address

Binary variable (1/0) denoting at least one public address

ISI

Private address

Binary variable (1/0) denoting at least one private address

ISI

Impact factor

Impact factor for journal in which paper is published

ISI/ Journal Citation Report

Patent characteristics

Patent in force

Binary variable (1/0) set to 1 if citation is received in years after patent grant

USPTO

Patent window

Binary variable (1/0) set to 1 if citation is received in year of patent grant

USPTO

Patent grant lag

Number of years between patent application and grant

USPTO

Patent scope

Number of national patent classes

USPTO

Number of claims

Number of claims in the patent

USPTO

Number of inventors

Number of inventors appearing on patent

USPTO

Number of patentees

Number of patentees appearing on patent

USPTO

Public patentee

Binary variable (1/0) denoting at least one public patentee

USPTO

All public patentee

Binary variable (1/0) denoting all public patentee

USPTO

Private patentee

Binary variable (1/0) denoting at least one private patentee

USPTO

All private patentee

Binary variable (1/0) denoting all private patentee

USPTO

US patentee

Binary variable (1/0) denoting at least one US-based patentee

USPTO

Patent-gene characteristics

Gene patents

Count of the number of patents for any given gene

USPTO/ Jensen and Murray (2005)

Gene fragmentation (herfgene)

Herfindahl measure of concentration of ownership for a given gene using assignees on list for gene patents

USPTO/ Jensen and Murray (2005)

OMIM gene

Binary variable (1/0) set to 1 if gene is listed in OMIM

OMIM

Cancer gene

Binary variable (1/0) set to 1 if gene is listed in Wellcome Cancer Gene Census

Wellcome Trust

Disease gene

Binary variable (1/0) set to 1 if gene is OMIM OR Cancer

OMIM/ Wellcome Trust

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2016 Springer Science+Business Media Singapore

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Huang, K.GL., Murray, F.E. (2016). Does Patent Strategy Shape the Long-Run Supply of Public Knowledge?. In: Liu, KC., Racherla, U. (eds) Innovation and IPRs in China and India. China-EU Law Series, vol 4. Springer, Singapore. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-10-0406-3_4

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-10-0406-3_4

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Singapore

  • Print ISBN: 978-981-10-0405-6

  • Online ISBN: 978-981-10-0406-3

  • eBook Packages: Law and CriminologyLaw and Criminology (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics