Skip to main content

Budget Rules and Budget Flexibility

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Balancing Control and Flexibility in Public Budgeting

Abstract

This chapter develops a simplified framework for conceptualizing budget control. It surveys the centrality of budgeting to organizational control, and focuses on the traditional model of public budgeting to better understand why its practices remain prevalent in government. The chapter develops a new taxonomy to characterize general ‘budget rules’ in the public sector and uses two of the most prominent rules (the ‘annuality’ and ‘purpose’ of spending) to explain how the rules operate through key properties of control. The chapter explores what high flexibility looks like for each of the budget rules and speculates on the implications for sustainable rule modification.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 39.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Or to put this another way, modernized public budgeting uses ‘third order controls’ to more effectively leverage the familiar ‘bureaucratic paradox’ that an efficient organization is one that must centralize in order to decentralize (Perrow 1977). This point will receive more treatment in Chap. 6.

  2. 2.

    The classic formulation of the key budgeting question in government is that coined by its namesake, V.O. Key, ‘On what basis shall it be decided to allocate x dollars to activity A instead of B?’ (Key 1940: 1138).

  3. 3.

    Budgeting research is multidisciplinary in that its key phenomena have been of interest in disciplines as diverse as economics, political science, public administration, organization studies, psychology, management, and accounting. We concede our characterization of the literature is reductive and inclined toward political science and management, but we note that the two broad approaches we discuss—‘routines’ and ‘economics’—are not inconsistent with other analytical frameworks (for example, Covaleski et al. 2003).

  4. 4.

    Limited in certain of these jurisdictions by the overriding authority of any written constitution, for example as is the case for the Commonwealth (or national) government of Australia.

  5. 5.

    We are not aware of this type of rule taxonomy having been developed specifically in the context of public budgeting. Some have articulated ‘classical rules’ of budgetary theory, most of which correspond with public finance principles about the relationship between taxation and expenditure (Jones and Pendlebury 2010). Similar taxonomic intentions inform other analyses of budget behavior, such as efforts to classify the incentive effects of budget controls for ‘strategic misrepresentation’ (Jones and Euske 1991). As we will see, some of these controls—budget constraints, program information asymmetry, detailed and rigid legislative oversight, temporal constraints, and excessive external audit of inputs—have some equivalency in the taxonomy we propose. By and large, though, efforts to develop ‘measurement instruments’ for budget control are to be found in the private sector context (see, for example, the micro-attributes for ‘tight budget control’ proposed in Van der Stede 2001).

  6. 6.

    In his discussion, Forster also sets out analysis to demonstrate why expenditure surge can be explained as ‘rational behavior’ in the sense that perfect ‘phasing’ of expenditure by public officials is not a realistic strategy for managing risk and uncertainty (Forster 1990: 104–108).

  7. 7.

    Having said this, it is important to recognize that even large components of operating expenses within the public sector are in effect nondiscretionary. These include, for instance, eligibility-based statutory entitlements and staffing costs (it is not uncommon for labor costs to account for three-quarters of operating expenses and, whether because of skill set demands or industrial relations arrangements, the related human capital is often not ‘fungible’).

  8. 8.

    This may be due to the increasing adoption of accrual accounting for budget management in the public sector, which deemphasizes the timing of cash transactions and, in theory at least, obviates the need for carryovers (Lienert and Ljungman 2009).

  9. 9.

    Bourdeaux surveys these issues in the context of sub-national (state) governments operating within the US separation-of-powers system, but the broader observations on the interaction between transfer rules and program definition have no less prescience in other political systems. For a more targeted critique of volatility in the way executive government defines and structures programs and outputs in a Westminster-based parliamentary system, see Carlin (2006).

  10. 10.

    Budgeting as continuous adjustment—where approved spending limits are a starting point for ‘rebudgeting’ during the reporting period—is certainly not unknown in government but is strongly associated with incrementalism and informality. For these reasons rebudgeting is often equated with ‘repetitive budgeting’ (Wildavsky 1986: 17–20), which is seen as an indicator of high levels of institutional incapacity and low levels of budget control.

References

  • Alesani, D. 2012. Rethinking budgeting as a continuous process. Public Administration Review 72(6): 885–886.

    Google Scholar 

  • Anders, K.K. 2001. Beyond results: Accountability, discretion and performance budget reform. London: JAI Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aubert, B.A., and S. Bourdeau. 2012. Public sector performance and decentralization of decision rights. Canadian Public Administration 55(4): 575–598.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bandy, G. 2015. Financial management and accountability in the public sector, 2nd ed. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boston, J., J. Martin, J. Pallot, and P. Walsh. 1996. Public management reform: The New Zealand model. Auckland: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bourdeaux, C. 2008. The problem with programs: Multiple perspectives on program structures in program-based performance-oriented budgets. Public Budgeting & Finance 28(2): 20–47.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carlin, T. 2006. Victoria’s accrual output based budgeting system: Delivering as promised? Some empirical evidence. Financial Accountability & Management 22(1): 1–19.

    Google Scholar 

  • Caza, A. 2012. Typology of the eight domains of discretion in organizations. Journal of Management Studies 49(1): 144–177.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cothran, D.A. 1993. Entrepreneurial budgeting: An emerging reform? Public Administration Review 53(5): 445–454.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Covaleski, M.A., J.H. Evans, J.L. Luft, and M.D. Shields. 2003. Budgeting research: Three theoretical perspectives and criteria for selective integration. Journal of Management Accounting Research 15: 3–49.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • DeHart-Davis, L. 2009. Green tape: A theory of effective organizational rules. Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory 19(2): 361–384.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • DeHart-Davis, L., J. Chen, and T.D. Little. 2013. Written versus unwritten rules: The role of rule formalization in green tape. International Public Management Journal 16(3): 331–356.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dittenhofer, M.A. 2001. Behavioral aspects of government financial management. Managerial Auditing Journal 16(8): 451–457.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Foldes, L. 1955. The delegation of authority to spend. Economica 22(87): 246–260.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Forster, J. 1990. Rational managerial behaviour, risk and expenditure surge in the public sector. In Budgetary management and control: The public sector in Australasia, ed. J. Forster and J. Wanna, 103–113. Melbourne: Macmillan.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Frow, N., D. Marginson, and S. Ogden. 2010. ‘Continuous’ budgeting: Reconciling budget flexibility with budgetary control. Accounting, Organizations and Society 35(4): 444–461.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Funnell, W., K. Cooper, and J. Lee. 2012. Public sector accounting and accountability in Australia, 2nd ed. Sydney: UNSW Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gray, A., and B. Jenkins. 1993. Horses to water: Budgeting, auditing and evaluation in seven governments. In Budgeting, auditing and evaluation: functions and integration in seven governments, ed. A. Gray, B. Jenkins, and B. Segsworth, 185–208. New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harris, J. 2013. Following the pound: The accounting officer in central government. London: Institute for Government.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harris, J., R. Hughes, G. Ljungman, and C. Sateriale. 2013. Medium-term budget frameworks in advanced economies: Objectives, design and performance. In Public financial management and its emerging architecture, ed. M. Cangiano, T. Curristine, and M. Lazare, 137–174. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hope, J., and R. Fraser. 2003. Beyond budgeting: How managers can break free from the annual performance trap. Cambridge: Harvard Business School Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hughes, O.E. 2003. Public management and administration: An introduction, 3rd ed. London: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hyndman, N., R. Jones, and M. Pendlebury. 2007. An exploratory study of annuality in the UK public sector: plus ca change, plus c’est la meme chose? Financial Accountability & Management 23(2): 215–237.

    Google Scholar 

  • Johansson, T., and S. Siverbo. 2014. The appropriateness of tight budget control in public sector organizations facing budget turbulence. Management Accounting Research 25(4): 271–283.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jones, L.R., and K.J. Euske. 1991. Strategic misrepresentation in budgeting. Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory 1(4): 437–460.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jones, R., and M. Pendlebury. 2010. Public sector accounting, 6th ed. Harlow: Pearson.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jones, L.R., and F. Thompson. 1986. Reform of budget execution control. Public Budgeting and Finance 6(1): 33–49.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jones, L.R., and F. Thompson. 2000. Responsibility budgeting and accounting. International Public Management Journal 3(2): 205–227.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keating, M., and M. Holmes. 1990. Australia’s budgetary and financial management reforms. Governance 3(2): 168–185.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Key, V.O. 1940. The lack of a budgetary theory. The American Political Science Review 34: 1137–1144.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lane, J-E. 1995. The public sector: Concepts, models and approaches. London: Sage.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lienert, I., and G. Ljungman. 2009. Carry-over of budget authority. Fiscal Affairs Department Public Financial Management Technical Guidance Note. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.

    Google Scholar 

  • MAC (Management Advisory Committee). 2004. Connecting government: Whole of government responses to Australia’s priority challenges. Canberra: MAC.

    Google Scholar 

  • Merchant, K.A. 1985. Organizational controls and discretionary program decision making: A field study. Accounting, Organizations and Society 10(1): 67–85.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mitchell, D., and K. Thurmaier. 2012. Currents and undercurrents in budgeting theory: Exploring the swirls, heading upstream. Public Administration Review Foundations of Public Administration Series. Washington, DC: American Society for Public Administration.

    Google Scholar 

  • Olson, O. 1990. Qualities of the programme concept in municipal budgeting. Scandinavian Journal of Management 6(1): 13–29.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Olson, O., J. Guthrie, and C. Humphrey (eds.). 1998. Global warning! debating international developments in new public financial management. Oslo: Cappelen Akademisk Forlag.

    Google Scholar 

  • Otley, D. 1999. Performance management: A framework for management control systems research. Management Accounting Research 10(4): 363–382.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Otley, D. 2006. Trends in budgetary control and responsibility accounting. In Contemporary issues in management accounting, ed. A. Bhimani, 291–307. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Pallot, J. 1991. Financial management reform. In Reshaping the state: New Zealand’s bureaucratic revolution, ed. J. Boston, J. Martin, J. Pallot, and P. Walsh, 166–197. Auckland: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Perrow, C. 1977. The bureaucratic paradox: The efficient organization centralizes in order to decentralize. Organizational Dynamics 5(4): 3–14.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rhodes, R., J. Wanna, and P. Weller. 2009. Comparing Westminster. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Robbins, D. 2005. Administrative discretion: Its use in budgetary analysis. Public Administration Quarterly 29(2): 186–200.

    Google Scholar 

  • Robinson, M. 2000. Contract budgeting. Public Administration 78(1): 75–90.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Robinson, M. 2007. Performance budgeting models and mechanisms. In Performance budgeting: Linking funding and results, ed. M. Robinson, 1–18. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Robinson, M., and H. van Eden. 2007. Program classification. In Performance budgeting: Linking funding and results, ed. M. Robinson, 63–87. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Rothman, G., and B. Thornton. 1990. Management of budgetary expenditures: The Commonwealth running costs system. In Budgetary management and control: The public sector in Australasia, ed. J. Forster and J. Wanna, 92–102. Melbourne: Macmillan.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Rubin, I. 1990. Budget theory and budget practice: How good the fit? Public Administration Review 50(2): 179–189.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schiavo-Campo, S., and H.M. McFerson. 2008. Public management in global perspective. New York: M. E. Sharpe.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schick, A. 1966. The road to PPB: The stages of budget reform. Public Administration Review 26(4): 243–258.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smith, P.C. 2007. Performance budgeting in England: Public service agreements. In Performance budgeting: Linking funding and results, ed. M. Robinson, 211–233. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Ter Bogt, H., G.J. Van Helden, and B. Van Der Kolk. 2015. Challenging the NPM ideas about performance management: Selectivity and differentiation in outcome-oriented performance budgeting. Financial Accountability & Management 31(3): 287–315.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thompson, F. 1993. Matching responsibilities with tactics: Administrative controls and modern government. Public Administration Review 53(4): 303–318.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tommasi, D. 2013. The budget execution process. In The international handbook of public financial management, ed. R. Allen, R. Hemming, and B. Potter, 285–311. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Van der Stede, W. 2001. Measuring ‘tight budgetary control’. Management Accounting Research 12(1): 119–137.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wildavsky, A. 1978. A budget for all seasons? Why the traditional budget lasts. Public Administration Review 38(6): 501–509.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wildavsky, A. 1979. The politics of the budgetary process, 3rd ed. Boston, MA: Little Brown.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wildavsky, A. 1986. Budgeting: A comparative theory of budgetary processes. Revised edition. New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2016 The Editor(s) (if applicable) and The Author(s)

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Di Francesco, M., Alford, J. (2016). Budget Rules and Budget Flexibility. In: Balancing Control and Flexibility in Public Budgeting. Palgrave Macmillan, Singapore. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-10-0341-7_4

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-10-0341-7_4

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Palgrave Macmillan, Singapore

  • Print ISBN: 978-981-10-0340-0

  • Online ISBN: 978-981-10-0341-7

  • eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics