Skip to main content

After History

The Last Frontier of Historical Capitalism

  • Chapter
Borderlines in a Globalized World

Part of the book series: Social Indicators Research Series ((SINS,volume 9))

Abstract

Old Boundaries. New Boundaries. Crossing Boundaries. Blurred boundaries. We live in a time of what seems to be a heightened sensitivity to the ways material and conceptual boundaries create limits and opportunities in the real world. To say that, however, is not to assert that hitherto social scientists have been unaware of the consequences of privileging one or another set of boundary-making criteria defining the what or whom they study. Indeed, what has come to be known as World-Systems Analysis arose amid, and took form through, critical reflection on the analytic object of inquiries into longterm, large-scale, social change.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Notes

  1. Roy C. Macridis ( 1963 (1955)): “A Survey of the Field of Comparative Government,” reprinted in Harry Eckstein and David E. Apter, Eds., Comparative Politics: A Reader ( Glencoe, Free Press ), pp. 43–52.

    Google Scholar 

  2. Gabriel A. Almond (1966 (1965)): “A Developmental Approach to Political Systems,” reprinted Jason L. Finkle and Richard W. Gable, Eds., Political Development and Social Change (New York, John Wiley & Sons), pp. 96–118, at p. 96.

    Google Scholar 

  3. The movement began with the creation of the Committee on Economic Growth of the Social Science Research council in 1950 by Simon Kuznets and a conference at the University of Chicago in 1951. It was institutionalized in the journal Economic Development and Cultural Change founded in 1952. For papers from the 1951 University of Chicago conference, see Bert F. Hoselitz, ed. (1952): The Progress of Underdeveloped Areas (Chicago, University of Chicago Press). For examples of representative work, see Bert F. Hoselitz and Wilbert E. Moore, Eds. (1963): Industrialization and Society (The Hague, UNESCO-Mouton) and Jason L. Finkle and Richard W. Gable, Eds. (1966): Political Development and Social Change ( New York, John Wiley & Sons).

    Google Scholar 

  4. Jacob Viner (1952), “America’s Aims and the Progress of Underdeveloped Countries,” Bert F. Hoselitz, ed.,: The Progress of Underdeveloped Areas (Chicago, University of Chicago Press), pp. 175–202, at pp. 175, 176.

    Google Scholar 

  5. Hoselitz (1952): p. v.

    Google Scholar 

  6. Alexander Gerschenkron (1952): “Economic Backwardness in Historical Perspective,” Bert F. Hoselitz, ed., The Progress of Underdeveloped Areas (Chicago, University of Chicago Press), pp. 3–29, at p. 29.

    Google Scholar 

  7. Morris Watnick (1952): “The Appeal of Communism to the Underdeveloped Peoples,” Bert F. Hoselitz, ed., The Progress of Underdeveloped Areas (Chicago, University of Chicago Press), pp. 152–72, at p. 172.

    Google Scholar 

  8. Wilbert E. Moore (1963): “Introduction: Social Change and Comparative Studies,” International Social Science Journal XV: pp. 519–527, at pp. 519–20.

    Google Scholar 

  9. Dorothy Ross (1991): The Origins of American Social Science (Cambridge, Cambridge University Press), p. 390. See Richard H. Wells and Steven J. Picou (1981): American Sociology: Theoretical and Methodological Structures (Washington, D.C., University Press of America), p. 115, for a quantification of the decline in interpretative studies and the rise in survey-based analyses: the latter reached 70% during the 1950–1964 period and 80% during the 1965–1978 period for the data set used.

    Google Scholar 

  10. American social science embraced the Durkheimian view that “assumes an indissoluble connection between theory and comparative method… ‘Comparative sociology is not a particular branch of sociology; it is sociology itself’.… In its broadest interpretation this canon of method emphasizes that a proper science deals with the general rather than the unique; a multiplicity of empirical cases must be brought together under the abstract categories of a theory,” wrote F. X. Sutton “Social Theory and Comparative Politics,” reprinted Harry Eckstein and David E. Apter, Eds. (1963 (1955)): Comparative Politics: A Reader (Glencoe, Free Press), pp. 67–81, at p. 67.

    Google Scholar 

  11. Almond (1966 (1965)): p. 97.

    Google Scholar 

  12. Sutton (1963 (1955)): p. 68.

    Google Scholar 

  13. E.g., Tönnies (Gemeinschaft-Gesellschaft),Maine (status-contract), Durkheim (mechanical-organic).

    Google Scholar 

  14. Sutton (1963 (1955)): p. 69.

    Google Scholar 

  15. Figuring prominently in the development of the structural-functionalist perspective were Bronislaw Malinowski, Alfred Radcliffe-Brown, Talcott Parsons, and Robert K. Merton. The Vienna Circle had rejected the view that distinguished between the natural and the social sciences and associated being itself with exhibiting a value on a variable. Paul Lazarsfeld, in collaboration with Robert K. Merton, institutionalized these principles at the Bureau of Applied Social Research at Columbia University. The form of social science they developed, based on survey research and statistical methods combined with structural-functionalist theory, became a model for the world.

    Google Scholar 

  16. E.g., S. N. Eisenstadt (1966): Modernization: Protest and Change ( Englewood Cliffs, N.J., Prentice-Hall)

    Google Scholar 

  17. W. W. Rostow (1964 (1956)): “Takeoff into Self-Sustained Growth,” Amitai Etzioni and Eva Etzioni, Eds., Social Change: Sources, Patterns, and Consequences (New York, Basic Books), pp. 275–90, at p. 289.

    Google Scholar 

  18. Paul A. Baran and E. J. Hobsbawm (1961): “The Stages of Economic Growth,” Kyklos 14: pp. 234–42, at p. 236.

    Google Scholar 

  19. See W. Baer (1962): “The Economics of Prebisch and ECLA,” Economic Development and Cultural Change X: pp. 169–82.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  20. Immanuel Wallerstein, ed. (1966): Social Change: The Colonial Situation (New York, John Wiley & Sons), pp. 1, 7.

    Google Scholar 

  21. Baran and Hobsbawm (1961): p. 237.

    Google Scholar 

  22. André Gunder Frank (1969 (1967)): Capitalism and Underdevelopment in Latin America: Historical Studies of Chile and Brazil,Revised Edition (New York, Monthly Review Press), p. 9. The construction of this relation over the long term, “the development of underdevelopment,” became the theme of dependency theorists.

    Google Scholar 

  23. Frank (1969 (1967)): pp. 10, xxi.

    Google Scholar 

  24. Frank (1969 (1967)): pp. xxi, 36.

    Google Scholar 

  25. Ernesto Laclau (1971): “Feudalism and Capitalism in Latin America,” New Left Review 67: pp. 19–38, at pp. 38, 25.

    Google Scholar 

  26. Paul Sweezy (1978(1953)): “A Rejoinder,” Paul Sweezy, et al., The Transition from Feudalism to Capitalism (London, Verso), pp. 102–8, at p. 105.

    Google Scholar 

  27. Immanuel Wallerstein (1979 (1974)): “The Rise and Future Demise of the World Capitalist System: Concepts for Comparative Analysis,” The Capitalist World-Economy (Cambridge, Cambridge University Press), pp. 1–36, at p. 10.

    Google Scholar 

  28. Wallerstein (1979 (1974)): p. 13.

    Google Scholar 

  29. Immanuel Wallerstein (1993): “World-System,” William Outhwaite and Tom Bottomore, Eds., The Blackwell Dictionary of Twentieth-Century Social Thought (Cambridge, MA, Blackwell), pp. 720–21, at p. 720.

    Google Scholar 

  30. Immanuel Wallerstein (1974): The Modern World-System 1: Capitalist Agriculture and the Origins of the European World-Economy in the Sixteenth Century (New York, Academic Press), p. 348. Beginning with The Modern World-System l and “The Rise and Future Demise of the World Capitalist System: Concepts for Comparative Analysis,” both published in 1974, Wallerstein has elaborated the consequences of the analytic model in a flood of books and articles, often in close collaboration with Terence K. Hopkins, or with students and scholars at the Fernand Braudel Center for the Study of Economies, Historical Systems, and Civilizations founded in 1976 at the State University of New York at Binghamton, or with other colleagues world-wide.

    Google Scholar 

  31. Immanuel Wallerstein (1979): “Theoretical Implications: A Roundtable Discussion Between Giovanni Arrighi, John Higginson, Bernard Magubane, John Saul, and Immanuel Wallerstein,” Review III: pp. 355360, at p. 357.

    Google Scholar 

  32. W allerstein (1974): p. 348.

    Google Scholar 

  33. I have explored this thesis, particularly the way rhetorical mechanisms were deployed in response to the Irish and Jamaican rebellions and the reform movement in England in the 1860’s and thereafter, in my “The Politics of Accumulation: Race, Gender, and the World Class Struggle in Victorian England,” under review.

    Google Scholar 

  34. The zones of “real existing socialism” were not excluded: the Leninist program, “not world revolution but anti-imperialism plus socialist construction… on inspection turned out to be mere rhetorical variants on the Wilsonian/Rooseveltian concepts,” argues Immanuel Wallerstein (1995): in After Liberalism (New York, New Press, 1995), pp. 137–38.

    Google Scholar 

  35. The answer contained in Terence K. Hopkins, Immanuel Wallerstein, et. al. (1996): The Age of Transition: Trajectory of the World-System, 1945–2025 ( London, Zed) is a definitive yes.

    Google Scholar 

  36. Such a stipulation is far from universally accepted. See, for instance, the essays, including Wallerstein’s response, in André Gunder Frank and Barry K. Gills, Eds. (1993): The World System: Five Hundred Years or Five Thousand ( New York, Routledge ).

    Google Scholar 

  37. The interrogation of the articulation among the now three structures of historical capitalism has only just begun. See Immanuel Wallerstein (1991): Unthinking Social Science: The Limits of Nineteenth-Century Paradigms (Cambridge, Polity Press); Gulbenkian Commission for the Restructuring of the Social Sciences (1996): Open the Social Sciences: Report of the Gulbenkian Commission on the Restructuring of the Social Sciences (Stanford, Stanford University Press); and my TimeSpace of Cultural Studies: English Cultural Studies in the Post-1945 World-System,under review.

    Google Scholar 

  38. I have set out the following argument in more detail in Richard Lee (1998): Complexity Studies and the Human Sciences: Pressures, Initiatives and Consequences of Overcoming the Two Cultures ( Mexico City, CIIECH).

    Google Scholar 

  39. René Descartes ( 1980 (1637)): Discourse on Method and Meditations on First Philosophy, translated by Donald A. Cress ( Indianapolis, Hackett ), p. 33.

    Google Scholar 

  40. Charles R. Bambach (1995): Heidegger, Dilthey, and the Crisis of Historicism ( Ithaca, Cornell University Press ), pp. 181–2.

    Google Scholar 

  41. Max Weber (1975): Roscher and Knies: The Logical Problems of Historical Economics, translated and with an Introduction by Guy Oakes (New York, Free Press ), p. 194.

    Google Scholar 

  42. Ernst Breisach (1983): Historiography: Ancient, Medieval, and Modern ( Chicago, University of Chicago Press ), p. 284.

    Google Scholar 

  43. John Stuart Mill ( 1988 (1843)): The Logic of the Moral Sciences ( La Salle, IL, Open Court), at p. 64.

    Google Scholar 

  44. See Wallerstein (1991): pp. 191–92.

    Google Scholar 

  45. For a comprehensive review of this literature, see Richard Lee (1992): “Readings in the `New Science’: A Selective Annotated Bibliography,” Review XV: pp. 113–71.

    Google Scholar 

  46. Eviatar Zerubavel (1997): Social Mindscapes: An Invitation to Cognitive Sociology ( Cambridge, MA, Harvard University Press).

    Google Scholar 

  47. Francis Fukuyama (1989): “The End of History?” The National Interest 16: pp. 3–18, at pp. 18, 4.

    Google Scholar 

  48. See Wallerstein (1995).

    Google Scholar 

  49. Elizabeth Deeds Ermarth (1992): Sequel to History: Postmodernism and the Crisis of Representational Time (Princeton: Princeton University Press), at pp. 4, 54, 16 (emphasis added).

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Authors

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2002 Springer Science+Business Media Dordrecht

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Lee, R.E. (2002). After History. In: Preyer, G., Bös, M. (eds) Borderlines in a Globalized World. Social Indicators Research Series, vol 9. Springer, Dordrecht. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-94-017-0940-8_4

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-94-017-0940-8_4

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Dordrecht

  • Print ISBN: 978-90-481-5979-6

  • Online ISBN: 978-94-017-0940-8

  • eBook Packages: Springer Book Archive

Publish with us

Policies and ethics