Skip to main content

The Valuation Problem

  • Chapter
Natural Resource Economics

Part of the book series: Recent Economic Thought Series ((RETH,volume 7))

Abstract

Economists are often asked to determine the values of commodities as part of cost-benefit analyses. Many goods and services are traded in organized markets, and it is reasonably straightforward to derive values for these commodities. Consumer surplus is given by the area under the inverse Marshallian demand curve and above the good’s market-clearing price. This so-called “welfare triangle” is an estimate of what consumers would be willing to pay for incremental units of the good (X i ) up to the actual level (X* i ) minus the amount they actually pay, which in turn equals X* i multiplied by the market price, P* xi .

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 39.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  • Bishop, R. C., and T. A. Heberlein. 1979. “Measuring values of extramarket goods: Are indirect measures biased?” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 61: 926–930.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bishop, R. C., T. A. Heberlein, and M. J. Kealy. 1983. “Contingent valuation of environmental assets: Comparisons with a simulated market.” Natural Resources Journal 23:619–633.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bishop, R. C., T. A. Heberlein, M. P. Welsh, and R. M. Baumgartner, 1984. “Does Contingent Valuation Work? Results of the Sandhill Experiment.” Invited paper, joint meetings of the Association of Environmental and Resource Economists, the American Agricultural Economics Association, and the Northeast Agricultural Economics Council. New York: Cornell University, August 5–8.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boadway, R. W., and D. E. Wildasin. 1984. Public Sector Economics. Boston: Little, Brown.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bockstael, N. E., and K. E. McConnell. 1981. “Theory and estimation of the household production function for wildlife recreation.” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 8:199–214.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bockstael, N. E., and K. E. McConnell. 1983. “Welfare measurement in the household function framework.” American Economic Review 73:806–814.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bockstael, N. E., W. M. Hanemann, and I. E. Strand, Jr. 1984. “Measuring the benefits of water quality improvements using recreation demand models. Volume II: Benefit Analysis Using Indirect or Imputed Market Methods.” Draft report to the Office of Policy Analysis, Office of Policy and Resource Management, U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, Washington, D. C.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bohm, P. 1972. “Estimating demand for public goods: An experiment.” European Economic Review 3:111–130.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boyle, K. J., and R. C. Bishop. 1984. “A Comparison of Contingent Valuation Techniques.” Department of Agricultural Economics Staff Paper no. 222, University of Wisconsin-Madison.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boyle, K. J., and R. C. Bishop. 1985. “The Total Value of Wildlife Resources: Conceptual and Empirical Issues.” Invited paper, Association of Environmental and Resource Economists Workshop on Recreational Demand Modelling, Boulder, Colorado, May 17–18.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boyle, K. J., R. C. Bishop, and M. P. Welsh. 1985. “Starting point bias in contingent valuation bidding games.” Land Economics, 61:188–194.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brookshire, D. S., R. C. d’Arge, W. D. Schulze, and M. A. Thayer. 1981. “Experiments in valuing public goods.” Advances in Applied Micro-Economics, vol. 1, ed. V. K. Smith. Greenwich, CT: JAI Press, pp. 123–172.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brookshire, D. S., M. A. Thayer, W. D. Schulze, and R. C. d’Arge. 1982. “Valuing public goods: A comparison of survey and hedonic approaches.” American Economic Review 72:165–177.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brown, G. M., Jr., and R. Mendelsohn. 1984. “The hedonic travel cost method.” Review of Economics and Statistics 66:427–433.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brown, G. M., Jr., and H. O. Pollakowski. 1977. “Economic valuation of shoreline.” Review of Economics and Statistics 59:272–278.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brown, J. N., and H. S. Rosen. 1982. “On the estimation of structural hedonic models.” Econometrica 50:765–768.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brown, W. G., and F. Nawas. 1973. “Impact of aggregation on the estimation of outdoor recreation demand functions.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 55:246–249.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brown, W. G., C. Sorhus, B. Chou-Yang, and J. A. Richards. 1983. “Using individual observations to estimate recreation demand functions: A caution.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 65:154–157.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Burt, O. R., and D. Brewer. 1971. “Estimation of net social benefits from outdoor recreation.” Econometrica 39:813–827.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Butler, R. V. 1982. “The specification of hedonic indices for urban housing.” Land Economics 58:96–108.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caulkins, P. P., R. C. Bishop, and N. Bouwes, Sr. 1984. “A Comparison of Two Travel Cost Models for Valuing Lake Recreation.” Department of Agricultural Economics Staff Paper no. 227, University of Wisconsin-Madison.

    Google Scholar 

  • Caulkins, P. P., R. C. Bishop, and N. W. Bouwes. 1985. “Omitted cross-price variable biases in the linear travel cost model: Correcting common misperceptions.” Land Economics 61:182–187.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cesario, F. J. 1976. “Value of time in recreation benefit studies.” Land Economics 52:32–41.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cesario, F. J., and J. L. Knetsch. 1976. “A Recreation Site Demand and Benefit Estimation Model.” Regional Studies 10:97–104.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cicchetti, C. J., A. C. Fisher, and V. K. Smith. 1976. “An economic evaluation of a generalized consumer surplus measure: The Mineral King controversy.” Econometrica 44:1259–1276.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ciriacy-Wantrup, S. V. 1952. Resource Conservation: Economics and Policy. Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Clawson, M. 1959. “Methods of Measuring the Demand for and Value of Outdoor Recreation.” Reprint no. 10. Washington, D. C.: Resources for the Future, Inc.

    Google Scholar 

  • Clawson, M., and J. L. Knetsch. 1963. “Outdoor recreation research: Some concepts and suggested areas of study.” Natural Resources Journal 3:250–275.

    Google Scholar 

  • Clawson, M., and J. L. Knetsch. 1966. Economics of Outdoor Recreation. Baltimore: John Hopkins University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coursey, D. L., et al. 1984. Experimental Methods for Assessing Environmental Benefits. Report to U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, contract Cr-8110077–01–0, Washington, DC.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cummings, R. G., D. S. Brookshire, D. L. Coursey, and W. D. Schulze. 1984. Valuing Environmental Goods: A State of the Arts Assessment of the Contingent Valuation Method. Washington, DC: Office of Policy Analysis, Office of Policy, Planning and Evaluation, U.S. Environmental Protection Agency.

    Google Scholar 

  • Davis, R. K. 1963. “Recreation planning as an economic problem.” Natural Resources Journal 3:239–249.

    Google Scholar 

  • Davis, R. K. 1964. “The value of bid game hunting in a private forest.” Transactions of the Twenty-Ninth North American Wildlife and Natural Resources Conference. 29:393–403.

    Google Scholar 

  • Deaton, A., and J. Muellbauer. 1980. Economics and Consumer Behavior. Cambridge, England: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Desvousges, W. H., V. K. Smith, and M. P. McGivney. 1983. A Comparison of Alternative approaches for Estimating Recreation and Related Benefits of Water Quality Improvement. Washington, DC: Economic Analysis Division, U.S. Environmental Protection Agency.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dwyer, J. F., J. R. Kelly, and M. D. Bowes. 1977. “Improved Procedures for Valuation of the Contribution of Recreation to National Economic Development.” University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign, Water Resources Center, UILU-WRC-77–0128.

    Google Scholar 

  • Edwards, S. F. 1984. “An Analysis of the Non-Market Benefits of Protecting Salt Pond Water Quality in Southern Rhode Island: An Application of the Hedonic Price and Contingent Valuation Techniques.” Unpublished Ph.D. dissertation, Department of Agricultural Economics, University of Rhode Island.

    Google Scholar 

  • Edwards, S. F., and G. D. Anderson. 1984a. “Land-use conflicts in the coastal zone: An approach for the analysis of the opportunity costs of protecting coastal resources.” Journal of the Northeast Agricultural Economic Council 13:73–81.

    Google Scholar 

  • Edwards, S. F., and G. D. Anderson. 1984b. “Valuing Non-Marginal Changes in the Water Quality of the Rhode Island Salt Ponds.” University of Rhode Island, Department of Resource Economics Staff Paper.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fisher, A., and R. Raucher. 1984. “Intrinsic benefits of improved water quality: Conceptual and empirical perspectives.” Advances in Applied Micro-Economics, vol. 3. ed. V. K. Smith and A. D. Witte, Greenwich, CT: JAI Press, pp. 37–66.

    Google Scholar 

  • Freeman, A. M., III. 1979. The Benefits of Environmental Improvement: Theory and Practice. Baltimore: John Hopkins University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Freeman, A. M., III. 1984. “On assessing the state of the arts of the contingent valuation method of valuing environmental changes.” In Valuing Environmental Goods: A State of the Arts Assessment of the Contingent Valuation Method, R. G. Cummings, D.S. Brookshire, D. L. Coursey, W. D. Schulze. Washington, DC: U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, pp. 180–195.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goodman, S. A. 1977. “Measuring the value of housing quality.” Journal of Regional Science 17:107–115.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Griliches, Z. 1961. “Hedonic price indices for automobiles: An econometric analysis of quality change.” Price Statistics of the Federal Government. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gum, R. L., and W. E. Martin. 1975. “Problems and solutions in estimating the demand for and value of rural outdoor recreation.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 57:558–566.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Halvorsen, R., and H. O. Pollakowski. 1981. “Choice of functional form for hedonic price equations.” Journal of Urban Economics 8:37–49.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hammack, J., and G. M. Brown. 1974. Waterfowl and Wetlands: Toward Bioeconomic Analysis. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hanemann, W. M. 1978. “A Methodological and Empirical Study of the Recreation benefits from Water Quality Improvement.” Unpublished Ph.D. dissertation, Department of Economics, Harvard University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hanemann, W. M. 1984. “Welfare evaluation in contingent valuation experiments with discrete responses.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 66:332–341.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hof, J. G., and D. A. King. 1982. “On the necessity of simultaneous recreation demand equation estimation.” Land Economics 58:547–552.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hof, J. G., and D. A. King. 1983. “On the necessity of simultaneous recreation demand equation estimation: Reply.” Land Economics 59:459–460.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hotelling, H. 1947. Letter to the National Park Service, June 18. Reprinted in: Economic Studies of Outdoor Recreation, Outdoor Recreation Resources Review Commission, Study Report no. 24, Washington, DC, 1962, p. 56.

    Google Scholar 

  • Johnson, M. S., and M. J. Lea. 1982. “Differential capitalization and public service characteristics.” Land Economics 58:189–203.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Just, R. E., D. L. Hueth, and A. Schmitz. 1982. Applied Welfare Economics and Public Policy. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D. 1984. “Comments on the Review Panel’s assessment.” Valuing Environmental Goods: A State of the Arts Assessment of the Contingent Valuation Method, R. G. Cummings, D. S. Brookshire, D. L. Coursey, W. D. Schulze. Washington, DC: U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, pp. 226–235.

    Google Scholar 

  • Knetsch, J. L. 1963. “Outdoor recreation demands and benefits.” Land Economics 39:387–396.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Knetsch, J. L., and R. K. Davis. 1966. “Comparison of methods for recreation valuation.” In Water Research. Ed. A. V. Kneese and S. C. Smith. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krutilla, J. V. 1967. “Conservation reconsidered.” American Economic Review 57:777–786.

    Google Scholar 

  • Li, M. M., and H. J. Brown. 1980. “Micro-neighborhood externalities and hedonic housing prices.” Land Economics 56:125–141.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lindahl, E. 1958. “Just taxation: A positive solution.” In Classics in the Theory of Public Finance. Ed. R. A. Musgrave and A. T. Peacock, London: Macmillan pp.168–177.

    Google Scholar 

  • Linneman, P. 1980. “Some empirical results on the nature of the hedonic price function for the urban housing market.” Journal of Urban Economics 8:47–68.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mäler, K. G. 1974. Environmental Economics: A Theoretical Inquiry. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1974.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marwell, G., and R. E. Ames. 1979. “Experiments on the provision of public goods. I. Resources, interest group size, and the free-rider problem.” American Journal of Sociology 84:1335–1360.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marwell, G., and R. E. Ames. 1980. “Experiments on the provision of public goods. II. Provision points, stakes, experience, and the free-rider problem.” American Journal of Sociology 85:926–937.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marwell, G., and R. E. Ames. 1981. “Economists free ride, does anyone else? Experiments on the provision of public goods. IV.” Journal of Public Economics 15:295–310.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McConnell, K. E. 1983. “Existence and bequest value.” In Managing Air Quality and Scenic Resources at National Parks and Wilderness Areas. Ed. R. D. Rowe and L. G. Chestnut. Boulder, CO: Westview Press, pp. 254–264.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mendelsohn, R. 1985. “Modelling the demand for outdoor recreation.” Invited paper, Association of Environmental and Resource Economists Workshop on Recreational Demand Modelling, Boulder, Colorado, May 17–18.

    Google Scholar 

  • Miller, J. R., and M. J. Hay. (1984) “Estimating substate values of fishing and hunting. “Proceedings of the 49th North American Wildlife and Natural Resources Conference.

    Google Scholar 

  • Milon, J. W., J. Gressel, and D. Mulkey. 1984 “Hedonic amenity valuation and functional form specification.” Land Economics 60:378–387.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mitchell, R. C., and R. T. Carson. 1981. An Experiment in Determining Willingnessto Pay for National Water Quality Improvements. Report prepared for U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, Washington, DC.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mitchell, R. C., and R. T. Carson. 1984a. “Some comments on the state of the arts assessment of the contingent valuation method draft report.” In Valuing Environmental Goods: A State of the Arts Assessment of the Contingent Valuation Method, R. G. Cummings, D. S. Brookshire, D. L. Coursey, W. D. Schulze, Washington, DC: U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, pp. 284–296.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mitchell, R. C., and R. T. Carson. 1948b. “Willingness to Pay for National Freshwater Quality Improvements.” Draft report to U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, Contract CR-810224–01–4. Washington, DC: Resources for the Future.

    Google Scholar 

  • Morey, E. R. 1981. “The demand for site-specific recreational activities: A characteristics approach.” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 8:345–371.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morey, E. R. 1984. “The choice of ski areas: Estimation of a generalized CES preference ordering with characteristics.” Review of Economics and Statistics 66:584–590.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oates, W. E. 1969. “The effects of property taxes and local public spending on property values: An empirical study of tax capitalization and the Tiebout hypothesis.” Journal of Political Economy 77:957–971.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Parsons, G. R. 1984. “Estimating Demand Functions for Attributes of a Differentiated Product.” Unpublished Ph.D. Dissertation, University of Wisconsin-Madison.

    Google Scholar 

  • Quigley, J. M. 1982. “Nonlinear budget constraints and consumer demand: An application to public programs for residential housing.” Journal of Urban Economics 12:177–201.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rae, D. A. 1981a. Visibility Impairment at Mesa Verde National Park: An Analysis of Benefits and Costs of Controlling Emissions in the Four Corners Area. Report prepared for the Electric Power Research Institute. Boston, MA: Charles River Associates.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rae, D. A. 1981b. Benefits of Improving Visibility at Great Smoky National Park. Report prepared for the Electric Power Research Institute. Boston, MA: Charles River Associates.

    Google Scholar 

  • Randall, A., and J. R. Stoll. 1983. “Existence value in a total valuation framework.” In Managing Air Quality and Science Resource at National Parks and Wilderness Areas. Ed. R. D. Rowe and L. G. Chestnut, Boulder, CO: Westview Press, pp. 265–274.

    Google Scholar 

  • Randall, A., B. Ives, and C. Eastman. 1974. “Bidding games for valuation of aesthetic environmental improvements.” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 1:132–149.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ridker, R. G. 1967. Economic Costs of Air Pollution: Studies in Measurement. New York: Praeger.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ridker, R. G., and J. A. Henning. 1967. “The determinants of residential property values with special reference to air pollution.” Review of Economics and Statistics 49:246–257.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roberts, D. J. 1974. “The Lindahl solution for economies with public goods.” Journal of Public Economics 3:23–42.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rosen, S. 1974. “Hedonic prices and implicit markets: Product differentiation in pure competition.” Journal of Political Economy 82:34–55.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Samples, K. C., and R. C. Bishop. (1985) “Estimating the value of variations in anglers’ success rates: An application of the multiple-site travel cost method.” Journal of Marine Resource Economics. 2:55–74.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scherr, B. A., and E. M. Babb. 1975. “Pricing public goods: An experiment with two proposed pricing systems.” Public Choice 23:35–48.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schulze, W. D., R. C. d’Arge, and D. S. Brookshire. 1981. “Valuing environmental commodities: Some recent experiments.” Land Economics 57:151–173.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Scott, A. 1965. “The valuation of game resources: Some theoretical aspects.” Canadian Fisheries Reports no. 4, Ottawa.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sellar, C., J. R. Stoll, and J. P. Chavas. 1985. “Validation of empirical measures of welfare change: A comparison of nonmarket techniques.” Land Economics 61:156–175.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shabman, L. A., and M. A. Bertelson. 1979. “The use of development value estimates for coastal wetland permit decisions.” Land Economics 55:213–222.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smith, V. K., and C. C. S. Gilbert. (1985) “The valuation of environmental risks using hedonic wage models.” In Horizontal Equity, Uncertainty and Economic Well Being. Ed. M. David and T. Smeeding, National Bureau of Economic Research. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, V. K., W. H. Desvousges, and M. P. McGivney. 1983. “The opportunity cost of travel time in recreation demand models.” Land Economics 58:259–278.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smith, V. L. 1977. “The principle of unanimity and voluntary consent in social choice. “Journal of Political Economy 85:1125–1139.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sutherland, R. J. 1982. “A Regional Approach to Estimating Recreation Benefits of Improved Water Quality.” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 9:229–247.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Talhelm, D. R. 1973. “Defining and evaluating recreational quality.” Transactions of the 38th North American Wildlife and Natural Resources Conference 38:183–191.

    Google Scholar 

  • Talhelm, D. R. 1981. “Defining angling supply, the key to recreational fishing evaluation.” Allocation of Fishery Resources. Ed. J. Grover. New York: UNFAO, pp. 443–451.

    Google Scholar 

  • Thayer, M. A. 1981. “Contingent valuation techniques for assessing environmental impacts: Further evidence.” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 8:27–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Trice, A. H., and S. E. Wood. 1958. “Measurement of recreation benefits.” Land Economics 34:195–207.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vaughan, W. J., and C. S. Russell. 1982. “Valuing a fishing day: An application of a systematic varying parameter model.” Land Economics 58:450–463.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ward, F. A. 1983. “On the necessity of simultaneous recreation demand equation estimation: Comment.” Land Economics 59:455–458.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Willig, R. D. 1976. “Consumer’s surplus without apology.” American Economic Review 66:587–597.

    Google Scholar 

  • Willis, C. E., and J. H. Foster. 1982. “The hedonic approach: No panacea for valuing water quality changes.” Journal of the Northeastern Agricultural Economics Council 12:53–57.

    Google Scholar 

  • Adams, Richard M., Scott A. Hamilton, and Bruce A. McCarl. 1984. “The Economic Effects of Ozone in Agriculture.” (Unpublished).

    Google Scholar 

  • Adams, Richard M., Narongsakdi Thanavibulchai, and Thomas D. Crocker. 1979. Methods Development for Assessing Air Pollution Damages for Selected Crops Within Southern California. Washington, DC: U.S. Environmental Protection Agency.

    Google Scholar 

  • Benedict, H. M., C. J. Miller, and J. S. Smith. 1973. Assessment of Economic Impact of Air Pollutions on Vegetation in the United States: 1969 and 1971. Palo Alto: Stanford Research Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bishop, Richard C. 1982. “Option value: An exposition and extension.” Land Economics 58:1–15.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Booz, Allen, and Hamilton, Inc. 1970. Study to Determine Residential Society Costs of Particulate Air Pollution. Research Triangle Park, North Carolina; National Air Pollution Control Administration.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brown, G., Jr, and J. H. Goldstein. 1984. “A Model for valuing endangered species.” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 11 (no. 4):303–309.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Courant, Paul N., and Richard Porter. 1981. “Averting expenditure and the cost of pollution.” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 8:321–329.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cummings, R., D. S. Brookshire, and W. D. Schulze. 1986. Valuing Environmental Improvements: A State of the Art Assessment of the Contingent Valuation Method. Rowman and Allenhelo, Totowa, N. J.

    Google Scholar 

  • Feenberg, Daniel, and Edwin S. Mills. 1980. Measuring the Benefits of Water Pollution Abatement. New York: Academic Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fisher, A. C., and W. M. Hanemann. 1986. “Option value and the extinction of species.” In Advances in Applied Mirco-economics, vol. 4. Ed. V. K. Smith. Greenwich, CT: J AI Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Freeman, A. Myrick III. 1979. The Benefits of Environmental Improvement: Theory and Practice. Baltimore: John Hopkins University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Freeman, A. Myrick, III. 1984. “The sign and size of option value.” Land Economics 60:1–13.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Freeman, A. Myrick, III. 1985. “Supply uncertainty, option price, and option value.” Land Economics 61:176–181.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gillette, D. G. 1975. “Sulfur dioxide and material damage,” Journal of the Air Pollution Control Association 25:1238–1243.

    Google Scholar 

  • Graham, Daniel A., 1981. “Cost-benefit analysis under uncertainty.” American Economic Review 71:715–725.

    Google Scholar 

  • Graham, D. A., 1984. “Cost-benefit analysis under uncertainty: Reply.” American Economic Review 74(no. 5):1100–1102.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harrington, W., and P. R. Portney. 1983. “Valuing the benefits of improved human health.” In Ambient Ozone and Human Health: An Epidemiological Analysis P. R. Portney and J. Mullahy. Washington, DC: Resources for the Future, Inc.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hori, H., 1975. “Revealed preference for public goods.” American Economic Review 65:978–991.

    Google Scholar 

  • Liu, B-C, and E. S. Yu. 1976. Physical and Economic Damage Functions for Air Pollutant by Receptors. Corvallis: Environmental Protection Agency.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lynn, G. D., P. Conway, and F. J. Prochaska. 1981. “Economic valuation of marsh areas for marine production processes.” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 8(no. 2):175–186.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mathtech, Inc. 1982. Benefits Analysis of Alternative Secondary National Ambient Air Quality Standards for Sulfur Dioxide and Total Suspended Particulates. Princeton, NJ: Mathtech.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mendelsohn, R., and W. J. Strang. 1984. “Cost-benefit analysis under uncertainty: Comment.” American Economic Review 74(no. 5):1096–1099.

    Google Scholar 

  • Michelson, I., and B. Tourin. 1966. “Comparative method for studying costs of air pollution.” Public Health Reports, 81:505–511.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Norton, B. G. 1982. “Environmental ethics and nonhuman rights.” Environmental Ethics 4:17–36.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rescher, N. 1980. Unpopular Essays on Technical Progress Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburg Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sagoff, M. 1980. “On the preservation of species.” Columbia Journal of Environmental Law 7:33–67.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schmalensee, Richard. 1972. “Option demand and consumer surplus: Valuing price changes under uncertainty.” American Economic Review 62:813–824.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, V. K. 1983. “Option value: A conceptual overview.” Southern Economic Journal 49:654–668.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smith, V. K., and W. Desvousges. 1983. “The Valuation of Risk Reductions Associated with Hazardous Waste Regulations.” Presented at the annual meetings of the Southern Economic Association, Washington, DC, November.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, V. K., W. H. Desvousges, and A. M. Freeman, III. 1985. Valuing Changes in Hazardous Waste Risks: A Contingent Valuation Analysis, Draft Interim Report. Paper presented to U.S. Environmental Protection Agency.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bockstael, N. E., W. M. Hanemann, and I. E. Strand. 1984. Measuring the Benefits of Water Quality Improvements Using Recreational Demand Models. Report to the U.S. Environment Protection Agency.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cropper, M. 1985. “Can the Rosen model be used to value location-specific amenities? Chapter 7 in Identification of Preferences in Hedonic Models. Ed. K. E. McConnell. Report to the U.S. Environmental Protection Agency.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ellickson, B. 1981. “An alternative test of the hedonic theory of housing markets.” Journal of Urban Economics 8:56–79.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Horowitz, J. L. 1983. “A Bidding Model of Urban Housing Markets with Disequilibrium and incomplete information.” Paper prepared for 30th North American Meeting of the Regional Science Association.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lerman, S. R., and C. R. Kern. 1983. “Hedonic theory, bid rents and willingness-to-pay: Some Extensions of Ellickson’s Results.” Journal of Urban Economics 10:358–368.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McConnell, K. E., and N. E. Bockstael. 1984. “Aggregation in recreation economics: Issues in estimation and benefit measurement.” Northeast Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics 13:187–198.

    Google Scholar 

  • McConnell, K. E., and T. T. Phipps, 1985a. “Identification of the parameters of the preference function: Consumer demands with nonlinear budgets.” Chapter 4 in Identification of Preferences in Hedonic Models. Ed. K. E. McConnell. Report to the U.S. Environmental Protection Agency.

    Google Scholar 

  • McConnell, K. E., and T. T. Phipps, 1985b. “The formation and use of the hedonic price equation.” Chapter 6 in Identification of Preferences in Hedonic Models. Ed. K. E. McConnell. Report to the U.S. Environmental Protection Agency.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Authors

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 1986 Kluwer-Nijhoff Publishing, Boston

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Anderson, G.D., Bishop, R.C. (1986). The Valuation Problem. In: Bromley, D.W. (eds) Natural Resource Economics. Recent Economic Thought Series, vol 7. Springer, Dordrecht. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-94-011-7426-8_3

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-94-011-7426-8_3

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Dordrecht

  • Print ISBN: 978-94-011-7428-2

  • Online ISBN: 978-94-011-7426-8

  • eBook Packages: Springer Book Archive

Publish with us

Policies and ethics