Advertisement

MARKAL Model with Elastic Demands: Application to Greenhouse Gas Emission Control

  • Richard Loulou
  • Denis Lavigne
Part of the Economics, Energy and Environment book series (ECGY, volume 5)

Abstract

MARKAL (Fishbone and Abilock, 1981; Berger et al, 1992) is a multi-period bottom-up model of energy-environment systems characterized by the high degree of disaggregation in the representation of the energy/technology options. MARKAL computes a competitive partial equilibrium on the energy market, where the endogenous energy prices are equal to the marginal values of the energy forms, and where demands for energy services are exogenously set by scenario. MARKAL is used in more than 20 countries, many of them members of the ETSAP consortium, which operates under implementing agreements from the International Energy Agency (IEA). Recent applications of MARKAL have focused on the analysis of Greenhouse Gas emission control (Kram, 1993).

Keywords

Price Elasticity Demand Curve Elastic Demand Energy Service International Energy Agency 
These keywords were added by machine and not by the authors. This process is experimental and the keywords may be updated as the learning algorithm improves.

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  1. Altdorfer, F. (July 1981). “Introduction of price elasticities on energy demand in MARKAL”, Memorandum No 345, KFA, Julich.Google Scholar
  2. Berger, C, Dubois, R., Haurie, A., Lessard, E., Loulou, R. and Waaub, J.-Ph. (1992). “Canadian MARKAL: an Advanced Linear Programming System for Energy and Environment Modelling”, INFOR, 20, pp. 114–125.Google Scholar
  3. Fishbone, L.G., and Abilock, H. (1981). “MARKAL, A Linear Programming Model for Energy Systems Analysis: Technical Description of the BNL Version”, International Journal of Energy Research, 5, pp. 353–375.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Hogan, W.W. (1975) “Energy Policy Models for Project Independence”, Computers and Operations Research, 2, pp. 251–271.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Kram, T. (1993). “National Energy Options for reducing C02 Emissions, Vol. 1: the International Connection”, ECN-C-93–101 Report, ECN, Petten, The Netherlands.Google Scholar
  6. Loulou, R., Lavigne, D. and Berger, C. (July 1994). “C02 Abatement in Quebec and Ontario: The Techno-Economic Envelope”, Report written for Environment Canada, Cahier du GERAD G-94–44.Google Scholar
  7. Manne, A.S., and Wene, C-O. (February 1992). “MARKAL-MACRO: A Linked Model for Energy-Economy Analysis”, BNL-47161 report, Brookhaven National Laboratory, Upton, New-York.Google Scholar
  8. Samuelson, P.A. (1952). “Spatial Price Equilibrium and Linear Programming”, American Economic Review, 42, pp. 283–303.Google Scholar
  9. Scheper, E., and Kram, T. (May 1994). “Comparing MARKAL and MARKAL-MACRO for The Netherlands”, ECN Policy Studies, Draft, presented at the May 1994 meeting of ETSAP.Google Scholar
  10. Takayama, T., and Judge G.G. (1971). Spatial and Temporal Price and Allocation Models, North Holland, Amsterdam.Google Scholar
  11. Tosato, G.C. (June 11–16 1980). “Extreme Scenarios in MARKAL LP Model: use of Demand Elasticity”, presented at the 5th Italian-Polish Symposium on Applications of Systems Theory to Economics and Technology, Torun.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Kluwer Academic Publisher 1996

Authors and Affiliations

  • Richard Loulou
    • 1
  • Denis Lavigne
    • 1
  1. 1.GERAD and McGill UniversityCanada

Personalised recommendations