Skip to main content

Public Policy and Human Happiness: The Welfare State and the Market as Agents of Well-Being

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Human Happiness and the Pursuit of Maximization

Part of the book series: Happiness Studies Book Series ((HAPS))

Abstract

The market and the welfare state are the institutions widely agreed to be the main alternatives available for generating and distributing human well-being. Contending arguments make powerful claims for the superiority of each, reflecting as they do the basic ideological division shaping political conflict in capitalist democracies. In this chapter we attempt an empirical appraisal of this issue, using the extent to which individuals find their lives to be satisfying as an evaluative metric. Considering rates of life satisfaction in the advanced industrial democracies, we find that satisfaction increases as the level of state intervention in the market economy increases. The data suggest that maximizing the “decommodification” provided by the welfare state does indeed help to maximize human happiness. We conclude with a discussion of the practical and theoretical ramifications of these findings.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    The intellectual infrastructure for studying subjective well-being is sufficiently developed and familiar so as not to require extensive elaboration. A voluminous literature has documented that conventional survey items utilized to measure subjective well-being are reliable and valid (for a discussion, see Myers and Diener 1995). After an exhaustive review, Veenhoven concludes that any misgivings about measurement “can be discarded” (Veenhoven 1996, p. 4). Similarly, the collective evidence strongly endorses the proposition that linguistic or cultural barriers (including social pressures for over—or under-reporting self reported satisfaction) do not meaningfully detract from our ability to make cross-national comparison (see, for example, Inglehart 1990 and Veenhoven 1996, 1997a, b). More recent literature equally supports this position. Kacapyr (2008), for instance, argues that subjective well-being indicators do warrant the confidence that the research has placed on them. Another literature, again conveniently summarized by Veenhoven (2002), convincingly argues for the theoretical appropriateness of subjective measures of quality of life, such as satisfaction, as opposed to purely objective indicators (such as income or other measures of consumption).

  2. 2.

    Countries in our study include: Australia, Austria, Belgium, Canada, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Great Britain, Greece, Ireland, Italy, Japan, The Netherlands, New Zealand, Norway, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, and The United States.

  3. 3.

    DiTella et al. (1997) referred to the residual method, when applied to nation states, as providing an estimate of a country’s “pure” level of satisfaction, meaning the amount of satisfaction that can be attributed to national characteristics per se. Radcliff (2001), who uses the same method, notes that this may overstate the case somewhat, since politics can influence at least some variables (e.g., income) that are potentially affected to at least some degree by government policy. Still, the procedure is useful because it is highly conservative, given that it assigns as much variance as possible to individual-level factors that are assumed to be apolitical, thus “raising the bar for showing that politics indeed affects average levels of satisfaction” (Radcliff 2001). This approach is familiar to students of American politics in the work of Erikson et al. (1993), who utilize the same logic to estimate states’ ideological cultures, i.e. they regress individual ideological orientations on demographic variables, and then include dummies for states, which in turn become their estimates of culture in the sense of being that variance not explained by individual-level variables. We use mean residuals (Radcliff 2001) instead of the value of the dummy variables, but the procedures are econometrically equivalent.

  4. 4.

    Details in the coding can be found in Appendix 1: Explanatory Notes and Data Sources, pp. 192–193 in the 2008 Economic Freedom of the World Report (http://www.freetheworld.com/2008/EFW2008App1.pdf).

  5. 5.

    The details of the rigorous operationalization are not readily summarized. Perhaps the most succinct description is offered by Messner and Rosenfeld (1997, p. 1399): the index “encompasses three primary dimensions of the underlying concept: the ease of access to welfare benefits, their income-replacement values, and the expansiveness of coverage across different statuses and circumstances. A complex scoring system is used to assess (the amount of decommodification provided by) the three most important social welfare programs: pensions, sickness benefits, and unemployment compensation. The scoring system reflects the ‘prohibitiveness’ of conditions for eligibility (e.g., means testing), the distinctiveness for and duration of entitlements (e.g., maximum duration of benefits), and the degree to which benefits replace normal levels of earnings. The indices for these three types of…programs are then aggregated into a combined (additive) index.” It should be noted that the individual indices are weighted by the percent of the relevant population covered by the given programs. Each dimensional index is built from multiple indicators (e.g., five for old age pensions, four each for sickness and unemployment) reflecting the concerns noted above. The data can be located at http://sp.uconn.edu/~scruggs/wp.htm (accessed on April 15 2008).

  6. 6.

    The Polity data set examines concomitant qualities of democracy and autocracy in governing institutions and spans a range of fully institutionalized autocracies through “mixed” or “incoherent authority” regimes, to fully institutionalized democracies. The Polity score captures this regime authority spectrum on a 21 point scale ranging from −10 (hereditary monarchy) to +10 (consolidated democracy). Full details may be found at the Polity data set website (http://www.systemicpeace.org/polity/polity4.htm).

  7. 7.

    Unemployment data are from the World Development Indicators 2006 edition CD-ROM, from the World Bank. (For more information, see: http://publications.worldbank.org/ecommerce/catalog/product?item_id=5612167).

  8. 8.

    Note again that this is the only case suggested by the diagnostic. Other conventional regression diagnostics suggest nothing untoward.

References

  • Allan J, Scruggs L (2004) Political partisanship and welfare state reform in advanced industrial societies. Am J Polit Sci 48(3):496–512

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clarke HD, Whiteley P, Sanders D, Stewart M (2010) Government performance and life satisfaction in contemporary Britain. J Politics 72(3):733–746

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diener E, Diener M, Diener C (1995) Factors predicting the subjective well-being of nations. J Pers Soc Psychol 69:851–864

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diener E, Suh EM, Lucas RE, Smith HE (1999) Subjective well-being: three decades of progress. Psychol Bull 125:276–302

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diener E, Suh EM (eds) (2000) Culture and subjective well-being. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • DiTella R, McCulloch R, Oswald A (1997) The macroeconomics of happiness. The labour market consequences of technical and structural change discussion paper series, number 19. Centre for Economic Performance, Oxford University

    Google Scholar 

  • Erikson RS, Wright GC, McIver JP (1993) Statehouse democracy: public opinion and policy in the American states. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Esping-Andersen G (1990) The three worlds of welfare capitalism. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Frey B, Stutzer A (2002) Happiness and economics. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Hirschman A (1991) The rhetoric of reaction: perversity, futility, jeopardy. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Huber E, Ruesschemeyer D, Stephens J (1992) Capitalist development and democracy. University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Inglehart R (1988) The renaissance of political culture. Am Polit Sci Rev 82(4):1203–1230

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Inglehart R (1990) Culture shift in advanced industrial democracies. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Inglehart R (2000) Globalization and post-modern values. Wash Q 23(1):215–228

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Inglehart R, Klingemann HD (2000) Genes, culture, democracy, and happiness. In: Diener E, Suh EM (eds) Culture and subjective well-being. MIT Press, Cambridge, pp 165–183

    Google Scholar 

  • Inglehart R, Welzel C (2005) Modernization, cultural change, and democracy: the human development sequence. Cambridge University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Kacapyr E (2008) Cross-country determinants with life. Int J Soc Econ 35(6):400–416

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lane RE (1978) Autonomy, felicity, futility. J Politics 40:1–24

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lane RE (2000) The loss of happiness in market democracies. Yale University Press, New Haven

    Google Scholar 

  • Layard R (2005) Happiness: lessons from a new science. Allen Lane, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Lindblom C (1977) Politics and markets. Basic Books, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Messner SF, Rosenfeld R (1997) Political restraint of the market and levels of criminal homicide: a cross-national application of institutional-anomie theory. Soc Forces 75(4):1393–1416

    Google Scholar 

  • Murray C (1984) Losing ground: American social policy, 1950–1980. Basic Books, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Myers D, Diener E (1995) Who is happy? Psychol Sci 6:10–19

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Radcliff B (2001) Politics, markets, and life satisfaction: the political economy of human happiness. Am Polit Sci Rev 95(4):939–952

    Google Scholar 

  • Radcliff B (2013) The political economy of human happiness: how voters’ choices determine the quality of life. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Scruggs L (2005) Comparative welfare entitlements dataset. Department of Political Science, University of Connecticut. Available at: http://sp.uconn.edu/~scruggs/wp.htm. Accessed 15 April 2008

  • Schyns P (1998) Cross-national differences in happiness: economic and cultural factors explored. Soc Indic Res 43:3–26

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Somers M, Block F (2005) From poverty to perversity: ideas, markets, and institutions over 200 years of welfare debate. Am Sociol Rev 70(2):260–287

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Soros G (1998) The crisis of global capitalism. Public Affairs, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Swank D (1988) The political economy of government domestic expenditure in the affluent democracies, 1960–1980. Am J Polit Sci 32(3):1120–1150

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Swank D (2001) Political institutions and welfare state restructuring: the impact of institutions on social policy change in developed democracies. In: Pierson P (ed) The new politics of the welfare state. Oxford University Press, New York, pp 197–237

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Triandis HC (1989) The self and social behavior in differing cultural contexts. Psychol Rev 96(3):506–520

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Veenhoven R (1996) Developments in satisfaction research. Soc Indic Res 37:1–46

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Veenhoven R (1997a) Advances in understanding happiness. Revue Quebecoise de Psychologie 18:29–74

    Google Scholar 

  • Veenhoven R (1997b) Quality of life in individualistic societies. In: DeJong M-J, Zijderveld AC (eds) The gift of society. Enzo Press, Netherlands, pp 149–170

    Google Scholar 

  • Veenhoven R (1999) Quality of life in individualistic society: a comparison of 43 nations in the early 1990s. Soc Indic Res 48:157–186

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Veenhoven R (2000) Well-being in the welfare state: level not higher, distribution not more equitable. J Comp Policy Anal 2(1):91–125

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Veenhoven R (2002) Why social policy needs subjective indicators. Soc Indic Res 58:33–45

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Robert Davidson .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2013 Springer Science+Business Media Dordrecht

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Davidson, R., Pacek, A.C., Radcliff, B. (2013). Public Policy and Human Happiness: The Welfare State and the Market as Agents of Well-Being. In: Brockmann, H., Delhey, J. (eds) Human Happiness and the Pursuit of Maximization. Happiness Studies Book Series. Springer, Dordrecht. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-94-007-6609-9_12

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics