Skip to main content

Knowledge, Capabilities, and the Poverty Trap: The Complex Interplay Between Technological, Social, and Geographical Factors

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Knowledge and the Economy

Part of the book series: Knowledge and Space ((KNAS,volume 5))

Abstract

This chapter explores the suggestion that technological capabilities, if they are to lead to development, need to be accompanied by a broad set of social capabilities reflecting not only such things as the provision of education and good governance, but also the spread of values, beliefs, and institutions that encourage members of society to contribute actively to the development process. The empirical analysis presented in the chapter, based on a large dataset of relevant indicators for countries at different levels of development, lends considerable support to this suggestion. However, the analysis also shows that some countries, mostly tropical, are disadvantaged by a powerful vicious circle of high fertility rates, low education, and high frequency of serious disease, which hamper the building of technological and social capabilities and perpetuate poverty. The authors conclude that there is no easy “technological fix” to the problem of underdevelopment.

This chapter is based on a presentation at the Fifth Interdisciplinary Symposium on Knowledge and Space, “Knowledge and the Economy,” June 25–28, 2008, Villa Bosch Studio, Heidelberg, organized by the Department of Geography, University of Heidelberg, and supported by the Klaus Tschira Foundation. The support from VINNOVA Core Funding of Centers for Innovation Systems Research (Grant agreement 2010–01370) is gratefully acknowledged. Jan Fagerberg would also like to thank International Centre for Economic Research, University of Torino, for its support during the final revision of the chapter. We have benefitted from suggestions from the participants of the symposium and an anonymous referee, retaining sole responsibility for the final version.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 129.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

References

  • Abramovitz, M. (1986). Catching up, forging ahead, and falling behind. Journal of Economic History, 46, 385–406.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Abramovitz, M. (1994a). The origins of the postwar catch-up and convergence boom. In J. Fagerberg, B. Verspagen, & N. von Tunzelman (Eds.), The dynamics of technology, trade and growth (pp. 21–52). Aldershot: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Abramovitz, M. (1994b). Catch-up and convergence in the postwar growth boom and after. In W. J. Baumol, R. R. Nelson, & E. N. Wolf (Eds.), Convergence of productivity—Cross-national studies and historical evidence (pp. 86–125). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., & Robinson, A. (2002). Reversal of fortune: Geography and institutions in the making of the modern world income distribution. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117, 1231–1294.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Adelman, I., & Morris, C. T. (1965). A factor analysis of the interrelationship between social and political variables and per capita gross national product. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 79, 555–578.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Adelman, I., & Morris, C. T. (1967). Society, politics, and economic development. Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aghion, P., & Howitt, P. (1992). A model of growth through creative destruction. Econometrica, 60, 323–351.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, A., Devleeschauwer, A., Easterly, W., Kurlat, S., & Wacziarg, R. (2003). Fractionalization. Journal of Economic Growth, 8, 155–194.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K. J. (1972). Gifts and exchanges. Philosophy and Public Affairs, 1, 343–362.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barro, R. J. (1991). Economic growth in a cross section of countries. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106, 407–443.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beck, T., Clarke, G., Groff, A., Keefer, P., & Walsh, P. (2001). New tools in comparative political economy: The database of political institutions. World Bank Economic Review, 15, 165–176.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beck, T., Keefer, P. E., Clarke, G. R., Walsh, P., & Groff, A. (2005). Database of political institutions. New York: World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bell, M. (1984). Learning and accumulation of industrial and technological capacity in developing countries. In M. Fransman & K. King (Eds.), Technological capability in the third word (pp. 187–209). London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Benhabib, J., & Spiegel, M. M. (1994). The role of human capital in economic development: Evidence from aggregate cross-country data. Journal of Monetary Economics, 34, 143–173.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bloom, D. E., Canning, D., & Sevilla, J. (2003). Geography and poverty traps. Journal of Economic Growth, 8, 355–378.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bourdieu, P. (1985). The forms of capital. In J. G. Richardson (Ed.), Handbook of theory and research for the sociology of education (pp. 241–258). New York: Greenwood.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cingranelli, D. L., & Richards, D. L. (2004). The Cingranelli-Richards (CIRI) Human Rights Dataset (Dataset version 1.0).

    Google Scholar 

  • Coe, D., & Helpman, E. (1995). International R&D spillovers. European Economic Review, 39, 859–887.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cohen, W. M., & Levinthal, D. A. (1990). Absorptive capacity: A new perspective on learning and innovation. Administrative Science Quarterly, 35, 128–152.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coleman, J. S. (1990). Foundations of social theory. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dahlman, C. J., & Westphal, L. E. (1981). The meaning of technological mastery in relation to transfer of technology. The Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science, 458, 12–26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dahlman, C. J., & Westphal, L. E. (1982). Technological effort in industrial development—An interpretative survey of recent research. In F. Stewart & J. James (Eds.), The economics of new technology in developing countries (pp. 105–137). London: Pinter.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dahlman, C. J., Ross-Larson, B., & Westphal, L. (1987). Managing technological development: Lessons from the newly industrialized countries. World Development, 15, 759–775.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Edquist, C. (1997). Systems of innovation: Technologies, institutions and organizations. London: Pinter.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fagerberg, J. (1987). A technology gap approach to why growth rates differ. Research Policy, 16, 87–99.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fagerberg, J. (1994). Technology and international differences in growth rates. Journal of Economic Literature, 32, 1147–1175.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fagerberg, J., & Srholec, M. (2005). Catching up: What are the critical factors for success? (Background paper for the UNIDO Industrial Development Report 2005). Vienna: United Nations Industrial Development Organization.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fagerberg, J., & Srholec, M. (2008a). National innovation systems, capabilities and economic development. Research Policy, 37, 1417–1435.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fagerberg, J., & Srholec, M. (2008b). Technology and development: Unpacking the relationship(s) (TIK Working Paper on Innovation Studies No. 20080623). Oslo: University of Oslo, Centre for Technology, Innovation and Culture.

    Google Scholar 

  • Figueiredo, P. N. (2006). Introduction [to special issue]. International Journal of Technology Management, 36, 1–13.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fransman, M. (1982). Learning and the capital goods sector under free trade: The case of Hong Kong. World Development, 10, 991–1014.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fransman, M., & King, K. (1984). Technological capability in the third world. London: Macmillan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Furman, J. L., Porter, M. E., & Stern, S. (2002). The determinants of national innovative capacity. Research Policy, 31, 899–933.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gallup, J. L., Sachs, J. D., & Mellinger, A. (1999). Geography and economic development (CID Working Paper No. 1). Cambridge: Harvard University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gerschenkron, A. (1962). Economic backwardness in historical perspective. Cambridge: The Belknap Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Görg, H., & Greenaway, D. (2004). Much ado about nothing? Do domestic firms really benefit from foreign direct investment?”. The World Bank Research Observer, 19, 171–197.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, G. M., & Helpman, E. (1991). Innovation and growth in the global economy. Cambridge: The MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Henisz, W. J. (2002). The institutional environment for infrastructure investment. Industrial and Corporate Change, 11, 355–389.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henisz, W. J. (2005). The Political Constraint Index (POLCON) dataset 2005. Philadelphia: Wharton School of the University of Pennsylvania.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kim, L. (1980). Stages of development of industrial technology in a developing country: A model. Research Policy, 9, 254–277.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kim, L. (1997). Imitation to innovation: The dynamics of Korea’s technological learning. Boston: Harvard Business School Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • King, R. G., & Levine, R. (1993). Finance and growth: Schumpeter might be right. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 108, 717–737.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Knack, S., & Keefer, P. (1997). Does social capital have an economic payoff? A cross-country investigation. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112, 1251–1288.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krueger, A., & Lindahl, M. (2001). Education for growth: Why and for whom? Journal of Economic Literature, 39, 1101–1136.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lall, S. (1987). Learning to industrialize: The acquisition of technological capability by India. London: Macmillan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lall, S. (1992). Technological capabilities and industrialization. World Development, 20, 165–186.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Landes, D. (1998). The wealth and poverty of nations. London: Abacus.

    Google Scholar 

  • Levine, R. (1997). Financial development and economic growth: Views and agenda. Journal of Economic Literature, 35, 688–726.

    Google Scholar 

  • Levine, R., & Zervos, S. (1998). Stock markets, banks, and economic growth. American Economic Review, 88, 537–558.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lucas, R. E. (1988). On the mechanics of economic development. Journal of Monetary Economics, 22, 3–42.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lundvall, B. Å. (1992). National systems of innovation: Towards a theory of innovation and interactive learning. London: Pinter.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marshall, M. G., & Jaggers, K. (2003). Polity IV dataset (Computer file; Version p4v2003). College Park: Center for International Development and Conflict Management, University of Maryland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Masters, W. A., & McMillan, M. S. (2001). Climate and scale in economic growth. Journal of Economic Growth, 6, 167–186.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, R. R. (1993). National innovation systems: A comparative analysis. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, R., & Phelps, E. S. (1966). Investment in humans, technological diffusion, and economic growth. American Economic Review, 56, 69–75.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ohkawa, K., & Rosovsky, H. (1974). Japanese economic growth. Stanford: Stanford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Portes, A. (1998). Social capital: Its origins and applications in modern sociology. Annual Review of Sociology, 24, 1–24.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Putnam, R. (1993). Making democracy work. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rodrik, D., Subramanian, A., & Trebbi, F. (2004). Institutions rule: The primacy of institutions over geography and integration in economic development. Journal of Economic Growth, 9, 131–165.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Romer, P. M. (1990). Endogenous technological change. Journal of Political Economy, 98, 71–102.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Romijn, H. (1999). Acquisition of technological capabilities in small firms in developing countries. Basingstoke: Macmillan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sachs, J. D., McArthur, J. W., Schmidt-Traub, G., Kruk, M., Bahadur, C., Faye, M., & McCord, G. (2004). Ending Africa’s poverty trap. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1, 117–240.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shin, J.-S. (1996). The economics of the latecomers: Catching-up, technology transfer and institutions in Germany, Japan and South Korea. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Solow, R. M. (1956). A contribution to the theory of economic growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 70, 65–94.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stata. (2005). Stata 9 data management reference manual. College Station: Stata Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Strand, H., Carlsen, J., Gleditsch, N. P., Hegre, H., Ormhaug, C., & Wilhelmsen, L. (2005) Armed conflict dataset codebook (Version 3-2005). Oslo: International Peace Research Institute (PRIO).

    Google Scholar 

  • Temple, J., & Johnson, P. A. (1998). Social capability and economic growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 113, 965–990.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weber, M. (2002). The protestant ethic and the spirit of capitalism (P. Baehr & G. C. Wells, Trans.). London: Penguin Books. (Original work published 1905)

    Google Scholar 

  • Woolcock, M., & Narayan, D. (2000). Social capital: Implications for development theory, research, and policy. World Bank Research Observer, 15, 225–250.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • World Values Survey Association. (2006). World Values Survey, 1981–2004, Official Aggregate v.20060423. Madrid: World Values Survey Association. Aggregate File Producer: ASEP/JDS. Retrieved from http://www.worldvaluessurvey.org

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Jan Fagerberg .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendices

Appendix A: Data and Sources

A brief overview of definitions, sources, and coverage of the indicators is given in Table 7.2. The main source of data is the World Bank (World Development Indicators), which combines various sources of data for a large sample of countries. The database has been complemented by data from other international organizations and datasets produced by research projects. National sources were used only for Taiwan when necessary and, in a few cases, for R&D data in developing countries.

Although the selected indicators have broad coverage, in some cases there were missing values that had to be estimated. We used the impute procedure in the Stata 9 to fill in the missing values (for details see Stata 2005). In each case we based our estimation on data for other indicators in the dataset. The number of countries with estimated data for each indicator is given in the last column of Table 7.2. We stress that considerable care was taken to check these estimated data against observed figures. If the estimated data exceeded the maximum (or minimum) observed value of an indicator elsewhere, we truncated the data by replacing the estimated values by the maximum (or minimum) observed figure. For some of the governance indicators, we also reversed the scale, though kept the original range, in order to present the indicators in increasing order (with low value signaling weak governance and high value signaling strong governance).

Table 7.2 An overview of the indicators

Appendix B

Table 7.3 Factor scores, by country

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2013 Springer Science+Business Media Dordrecht.

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Fagerberg, J., Srholec, M. (2013). Knowledge, Capabilities, and the Poverty Trap: The Complex Interplay Between Technological, Social, and Geographical Factors. In: Meusburger, P., Glückler, J., el Meskioui, M. (eds) Knowledge and the Economy. Knowledge and Space, vol 5. Springer, Dordrecht. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-94-007-6131-5_7

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics