Skip to main content

Theoretical Approaches to Dynamic Efficiency in Policy Contexts: The Case of Renewable Electricity

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
The Dynamics of Environmental and Economic Systems
  • 1486 Accesses

Abstract

Dynamic efficiency (or the ability of a policy instrument to generate a continuous incentive for technical improvements and cost reductions in technologies) is central to the assessment and choice of environmental and energy policies in long-run scenarios where innovation lock-in is relevant. This is also the case in instruments that support electricity from renewable energy sources (RES-E). In contrast with effectiveness and static efficiency assessment criteria, the innovation effects of such support have received much less attention from both a theoretical and an empirical perspective. Several theoretical perspectives have paid some attention to these innovation effects, including the traditional economics approach, the systems of innovation perspective and the literature on learning effects. The aims of this chapter are to provide an overview of those perspectives and to build bridges between them.

The work in this paper has been supported by a mobility grant awarded by the Spanish Ministry of Science and Innovation to Mercedes Bleda as a visiting Research Fellow at the CCHS, CSIC.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

eBook
USD 16.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    However, some authors are doubtful about the relative importance of dynamic efficiency criteria compared with more traditional, static efficiency criteria. For example, Parry et al. (2003) stress that the welfare gain from innovation is sometimes not much greater than the welfare gain of efficiently abating pollutants by means of conventional technologies. Requate (2005) observes that resources to engage in R&D are scarce. Hence, environmental technological progress may crowd out other strands of welfare enhancing technological progress. Finally, Fischer and Newell (2008) argue that the underlying process of technological change turns out to be far less important than the incentives to use technology efficiently to reduce emissions.

  2. 2.

    Following Marechal (2007), we use the word traditional to avoid the problems arising from the somewhat ambiguous use of the term neoclassical. Traditional economics refers to the Walrasian model of welfare economics, which can be defined as the theoretical synthesis of the Marshallian approach with marginal production theory (Marechal 2007).

  3. 3.

    A stream of the economic literature on climate change mitigation has applied an evolutionary approach with the aim of emphasising the inertia in current technological systems (Kemp 1996; Unruh 2000, 2002; Marechal 2007; del Río and Unruh 2007; Rip and Kemp 1998; Foxon et al. 2005).

  4. 4.

    Assessment in terms of system functions is one of the main approaches of the systems of innovation literature. Other innovation system studies have placed more emphasis on structural analyses (Carlsson et al. 2002; Jacobsson and Johnson 2000). Currently, some authors are concentrating on the integration of both approaches (Markard and Truffer 2008).

  5. 5.

    For example, in his analysis of wind energy deployment and policy in Denmark, Spain and Sweden, Meyer (2007) provides empirical evidence of the role of the coalition of forces in encouraging wind energy in Spain.

  6. 6.

    The assessment of Astrand and Neij (2006) shows that early inflexible steering of technology and market development, together with a lack of comprehensive, long-term strategy, lack of continuity in policy interventions and weak combinations of policy programmes and measures, have contributed to very limited wind power development in Sweden.

  7. 7.

    For example, Junginger et al. (2006) show that for technologies developed on a local level (e.g. biogas plants), learning-by-using and learning-by-interacting are important learning mechanisms whereas for CHP plants utilising fluidised bed boilers, upscaling is probably one of the main mechanisms behind cost reductions. Nemet and Baker (2010) show that certain components of the costs of solar PV improved with R&D investment, whereas others responded to increased deployment of the technology.

  8. 8.

    Some authors have stressed the difficulties in building learning curves for some renewable energy technologies (Junginger et al. 2006) or criticised the learning curve model itself (Kahouli-Brahmi 2008).

  9. 9.

    For a recent analysis of (observed) learning rates for various electricity supply technologies, see IEA (2008) and Kahouli-Brahmi (2008), among others.

  10. 10.

    The literature seems to be too polarised in this respect, with theoretical and empirical studies following either one or the other approach. Exceptions are Rogge and Hoffmann (2010) and Walz and Schleich (2009).

  11. 11.

    Indeed, learning effects introduce nonlinearities and positive feedbacks into the models in which they are used (the more a technology is used, the greater the incentive for using it more) (McDonald and Schrattenholzer 2001).

  12. 12.

    Watanabe et al. (2000) convincingly showed that the political environment behind Japanese government support for PV innovation was critical in developing the interindustry partnerships basic public research and broad-based market promotion for this fledging industry which in turn led to and was a result of learning effects. The authors analysed the Japanese solar PV Sunshine Project which aimed to encourage the broad involvement of cross-sectoral industry, stimulate inter-technology stimulation and cross-sectoral technology spillover and induce vigorous industry investment in PV R&D, leading to an increase in industry’s PV technology knowledge stock. They showed that an increase in this technology knowledge stock contributed to a dramatic increase in solar cell production. These increases led to a dramatic decrease in solar cell production price, and this decrease induced a further increase in solar cell production. An increase in solar cell production induced further PV R&D, thus creating a “virtuous cycle” between R&D, market growth, learning effects and price reduction.

  13. 13.

    For example, in the analysis of the Dutch wind-offshore sector, Smit et al. (2007) argued that there was weak learning-by-interacting by the actors from the industrial part of the technology system, who should get better access to actors in academia and actors in the oil and gas industry. The authors showed that there were several barriers hindering this interaction process. In contrast, they also showed that in the Danish case, learning-by-interacting occurred between knowledge institutes, component suppliers, project operators and turbine manufacturers and Danish policies contributed to the formation of these interactions.

References

  • Arrow, K. J. (1962). The economic implications of learning by doing. Review of Economic Studies, 29, 155–173.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Astrand, K., & Neij, L. (2006). An assessment of governmental wind power programmes in Sweden—using a systems approach. Energy Policy, 34, 277–296.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bergek, A., Jacobsson, S., Carlsson, B., Lindmark, S., & Rickne, A. (2008). Analyzing the functional dynamics of technological innovation systems – A scheme of analysis. Research Policy, 37(3), 407–429.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carlsson, B., Jacobsson, S., Holmen, M., & Rickne, A. (2002). Innovation systems: Analytical and methodological issues. Research Policy, 31(2), 233–245.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Del Río, P. (2009). The empirical analysis of the determinants for environmental technological change: A research agenda. Ecological Economics, 68(3), 861–878.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Del Río, P., & Gual, M. (2004). The promotion of green electricity in Europe: Present and future. European Environment Journal, 14, 219–234.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Del Río, P., & Unruh, G. (2007). Overcoming the lock-out of renewable energy technologies in Spain: The cases of wind and solar electricity. Renewable and Sustainable Energy Review, 11(7), 1498–1513.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Edenhofer, O., Carraro C., Hourcade J.-C., Neuhoff K., Luderer G., Flachsland C., Jakob M., Popp A., Steckel J., Strohschein J., Bauer N., Brunner S., Leimbach M., Lotze-Campen H., Bosetti V., de Cian E., Tavoni M., Sassi O., Waisman H., Crassous-Doerfler R., Monjon S., Dröge S., van Essen H., del Río P., Türk A. et al. (Ed.) (2009). The Economics of decarbonization (Report of the RECIPE Project). Potsdam: Potsdam-Institute for Climate Impact Research.

    Google Scholar 

  • Edquist, C. (2005). Systems of innovation: Perspectives and challenges. In J. Fagerberg, D. Mowery, & R. Nelson (Eds.), Oxford handbook of innovation (pp. 181–208). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Edquist, C., & Johnson, B. (1997). Institutions and organisations in systems of innovation. In C. Edquist (Ed.), Systems of innovation: Technologies, institutions and organizations. London/Washington: Pinter/Cassell Academic.

    Google Scholar 

  • Faber, A., & Frenken, K. (2009). Models in evolutionary economics and environmental policy: Towards an evolutionary environmental economics. Technological Forecasting and Social Change, 76, 462–470.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fischer, C., & Newell, R. (2008). Environmental and technology policies for climate mitigation. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 55(2), 142–162.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Foxon, T., & Andersen, M. (2009). The greening of innovation systems for eco-innovation – Towards an evolutionary climate mitigation policy. Paper presented at the Summer DRUID Conference, Copenhagen Business School.

    Google Scholar 

  • Foxon, T., Gross, R., Chase, A., Howes, J., Arnall, A., & Anderson, D. (2005). U.K. Innovation systems for new and renewable energy technologies: Drivers, barriers and systems failures. Energy Policy, 33, 2123–2137.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Geels, F., & Schot, J. (2007). Typology of sociotechnical transition pathways. Research Policy, 36, 399–417.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grübler, A., Nakicenovic, N., & Victor, D. (1999). Dynamics of energy technologies and global change. Energy Policy, 27(5), 247–280.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hekkert, M., & Negro, S. (2009). Functions of innovation systems as a framework to understand sustainable technological change: Empirical evidence from earlier claims. Technological Forecasting and Social Change, 76, 584–594.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hekkert, M., Suurs, R., Negro, S., Kuhlmann, S., & Smits, R. (2007). Functions of innovation systems: A new approach for analysing technological change. Technological Forecasting and Social Change, 74, 413–432.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hicks, J. (1932). The theory of wages. London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • IEA. (2008). Energy technology perspectives. Paris: IEA.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jacobsson, S. (2008). The emergence and troubled growth of a ‘biopower’ innovation system in Sweden. Energy Policy, 36, 1491–1508.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jacobsson, S., & Bergek, A. (2004). Transforming the energy sector: The evolution of technology systems in renewable energy technology. Industrial and Corporate Change, 13(5), 815–849.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jacobsson, S., & Johnson, A. (2000). The diffusion of renewable energy technology: An analytical framework and key issues for research. Energy Policy, 28(9), 625–640.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jaffe, A. B., Newell, R., & Stavins, R. (2002). Environmental policy and technological change. Environment and Resource Economics, 22(1–2), 41–69.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jaffe, A. B., Newell, R., & Stavins, R. (2005). A tale of two market failures: Technology and environmental policy. Ecological Economics, 54(2–3), 164–174.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Junginger, M., de Visser, E., Hjort-Gregersen, K., Koornneef, J., Raven, R., Faaij, A., & Turkenburg, W. (2006). Technological learning in bioenergy systems. Energy Policy, 34, 4024–4041.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahouli-Brahmi, S. (2008). Technological learning in energy–environment–economy modelling: A survey. Energy Policy, 36, 138–162.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kalowekamo, J.,& Baker, E. (2009). Estimating the manufacturing cost of purely organic solar cells. Solar Energy, 83(8), 1224–1231.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kemp, R. (1996). The transition from hydrocarbons: The issues for policy. In S. Faucheux, D. W. Pearce, & J. Proops (Eds.), Models of sustainable development (pp. 151–175). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kneese, A., & Schulze, C. (1975). Pollution, prices, and public policy. Washington, DC: Brookings Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Köhler, J., Grubb, M., Popp, D., & Edenhofer, O. (2006). The transition to endogenous technical change in climate-economy models: A technical overview to the innovation modelling comparison project. Energy Journal, 27, 17–56.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lee, B., Lliev, L., & Preston, F. (2009). Who owns our low carbon future? Intellectual property and energy technologies. London: Chatham House Report.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lundvall, B. (1988). Innovation as an interactive process: From user-producer interaction to the national system of innovation. In G. Dosi et al. (Eds.), Technical change and economic theory. London: Pinter Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lundvall, B. (1992). National systems of innovation. London: Printer Publisher.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lundvall, B., & Johnson, B. (1994). The learning economy. Journal of Industry Studies, 1(2), 23–42.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Malerba, F. (2004). Sectoral systems of innovation: Basic concepts. In F. Malerba (Ed.), Sectoral systems of innovation: Concepts, issues and analyses of six major sectors (pp. 9–41). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Marechal, K. (2007). The economics of climate change and the change for climate in economics. Energy Policy, 35(10), 5181–5194.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Markard, J., & Truffer, B. (2008). Technological innovation systems and the multi-level perspective: Towards an integrated Framework. Research Policy, 37, 596–615.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Markard, J., Stadelmann, M., & Truffer, B. (2009). Analysis of variation in innovation systems. Identifying potential development options for biogas in Switzerland. Research Policy, 38(4), 655–667.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McDonald, A., & Schrattenholzer, L. (2001). Learning rates for energy technologies. Energy Policy, 29(4), 255–261.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meyer, N. (2007). Learning from wind energy policy in the EU: Lessons from Denmark, Sweden and Spain. European Environment, 17, 347–362.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Negro, S., Hekkert, M., & Smits, R. (2007). Explaining the failure of the Dutch innovation system for biomass digestion—A functional analysis. Energy Policy, 35, 925–938.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nemet, G., & Baker, E. (2010). Demand subsidies versus R&D: Comparing the uncertain impacts of policy on a pre-commercial low-carbon energy technology. The Energy Journal, 30(4), 49–80.

    Google Scholar 

  • Newell, R. (2008). A U.S. innovation strategy for climate change mitigation (Discussion Paper 2008-15; Hamilton Project). Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution.

    Google Scholar 

  • Newell, R. (2010). The role of markets and policies in delivering innovation for climate change mitigation. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 26(2), 253–269.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nill, J., & Kemp, R. (2009). Evolutionary approaches for sustainable innovation policies: From niche to paradigm. Research Policy, 38(4), 668–680.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Palmer, K., & Burtraw, D. (2005). Cost-effectiveness of renewable electricity policies. Energy Economics, 27(6), 873–894.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Parry, I., Pizer, W., & Fischer, C. (2003). How large are the welfare gains from technological innovation induced by environmental policies? Journal of Regulatory Economics, 23(3), 237–255.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Popp, D. (2010). Innovation and climate policy (NBER Working Paper 15673). Cambridge: NBER. http://www.nber.org/papers/w15673

  • Requate, T. (2005). Dynamic incentives by environmental policy instruments—A survey. Ecological Economics, 54, 175–195.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rip, A., & Kemp, R. (1998). Technological change. In S. Rayner & E. Malone (Eds.), Human choice and climate change (Vol. 2, pp. 327–399). Columbus: Battelle.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rogge, K., & Hoffmann, V. (2010). The impact of the EU ETS on the sectoral innovation system of power generation technologies – Findings for Germany. Energy Policy, 38, 7639–7652.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rosenberg, N. (1982). Inside the black box: Technology and economics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sagar, A., & van der Zwaan, B. (2006). Technological innovation in the energy sector: R&D, deployment and learning-by-doing. Energy Policy, 34, 2601–2608.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smit, T., Junginger, M., & Smits, R. (2007). Technological learning in offshore wind energy: Different roles of the government. Energy Policy, 35, 6431–6444.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smits, R., & Kuhlmann, S. (2004). The rise of systemic instruments in innovation policy. International Journal of Foresight and Innovation Policy, 1(1), 4–32.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Suurs, R., & Hekkert, M. (2009). Cumulative causation in the formation of a technological innovation system: The case of biofuels in the Netherlands. Technological Forecasting and Social Change, 76, 1003–1020.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Taylor, M. (2008). Beyond technology-push and demand-pull: Lessons from California’s solar policy. Energy Economics, 30, 2829–2854.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Unruh, G. (2000). Understanding carbon lock-in. Energy Policy, 28(12), 817–830.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Unruh, G. (2002). Escaping carbon lock-in. Energy Policy, 30, 317–325.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van Mierlo, B., Leeuwis, C., Smiths, R., & Woolthuis, R. (2010). Learning towards system innovation: Evaluating a systemic instrument. Technological Forecasting and Social Change, 77(2), 318–334.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Verbruggen, A. (2009). Performance evaluation of renewable energy support policies, applied on Flanders’ tradable certificates system. Energy Policy, 37(4), 1385–1394.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Walz, R., & Schleich, J. (2009). The economics of climate change policies: Macroeconomic effects, structural adjustments and technological change. Heidelberg: Physica Verlag, Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Watanabe, C., Wakabayashi, K., & Miyazawa, T. (2000). Industrial dynamism and the creation of a virtuous cycle between R&D, market growth and price reduction. The case of Photovoltaic Power Generation (PV) development in Japan. Technovation, 20(6), 299–312.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Woolthuis, R., Lankhuizen, M., & Gilsing, V. (2005). A system failure framework for innovation policy design. Technovation, 25, 609–661.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Pablo Del Río .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2012 Springer Science+Business Media Dordrecht

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Del Río, P., Bleda, M. (2012). Theoretical Approaches to Dynamic Efficiency in Policy Contexts: The Case of Renewable Electricity. In: Costantini, V., Mazzanti, M. (eds) The Dynamics of Environmental and Economic Systems. Springer, Dordrecht. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-94-007-5089-0_3

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics