Skip to main content

The Regrettable Loss of Mathematical Molding in Econometrics

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Book cover Mechanism and Causality in Biology and Economics

Part of the book series: History, Philosophy and Theory of the Life Sciences ((HPTL,volume 3))

Abstract

Although most accounts on causality discuss the specific role statistics and theory should have, it is taken for granted that they at least have a role in finding causal structures. The role for mathematics is not so obvious. However, before what is called the Probabilistic Revolution in econometrics, identification of causal relations was not a matter of economic-theoretical and statistical significance alone. Mathematical molding was considered as an essential tool in finding significant causal factors. In the 1940s, mathematical molding disappeared in the changeover from methods to specify causal mechanisms of business cycles to methods to identify economic structures, that is, invariant relationships underlying the workings of an economy. Mathematical molding could fulfill its role in modeling business cycle mechanisms because of the assumed close connection between mathematical representations of the business-cycle phenomenon and those of the explanatory mechanism. When the econometric program shifted its focus from mechanisms explaining phenomena to uncovering structural relationships, direct feedback from the phenomenon to the mechanism was lost and the role of mathematical molding ceased to exist.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 129.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    See, for example, the opening sentence of Aldrich’s (1989) paper on Autonomy: “Knowledge of structure is valuable and available – but only to those prepared to use both economic theory and statistical analysis.”

  2. 2.

    This explains the name “quadrature theory.” Quadrature stands for the process of determining the area of a plane geometric figure by dividing it into a collection of shapes of known area (usually rectangles) and then finding the sum of these areas. The integral denotes this process for infinitesimal rectangles.

  3. 3.

    Translated by the author.

  4. 4.

    This was not Frisch’s terminology, but Koopmans’. Aldrich (1994) gives an account of the development of the identification theory from Frisch to Koopmans by focusing on Haavelmo (1944), including a discussion of the change in terminology.

  5. 5.

    Boumans (1995), which discusses the more technical details of Frisch’s memorandum, also provides the derivation of this rule.

  6. 6.

    In Boumans (2005), it is shown that Haavelmo’s definitions of potential and factual influences can be represented in this way.

  7. 7.

    Both monographs are considered as containing the main body of the Cowles Commission’s theoretical results (see Christ 1994, p. 32).

  8. 8.

    For a more sophisticated account of this convergence, see Chao (2009), where he distinguishes between the invariance view and the theory view. Autonomy is equivalent to invariance but “does not say anything about the constitution of a system” (p. 71). So, the convergence is best described as the “invariance view of structure.”

References

  • Aftalion, Albert. 1927. The theory of economic cycles based on the capitalistic technique of production. Review of Economic Statistics 9(4): 165–170.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aldrich, John. 1989. Autonomy. In History and methodology of econometrics, ed. N. de Marchi and C. Gilbert, 15–34. Oxford: Clarendon.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aldrich, John. 1994. Haavelmo’s identification theory. Econometric Theory 10: 198–219.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boumans, Marcel. 1995. Frisch on testing of business cycle theories. Journal of Econometrics 67(1): 129–147.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boumans, Marcel. 1999. Built-in justification. In Models as mediators, ed. M.S. Morgan and M. Morrison, 66–96. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Boumans, Marcel. 2005. How economists model the world into numbers. London/New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bullock, Charles J., Warren M. Persons, and William L. Crum. 1927. The construction and interpretation of the Harvard index of business conditions. Review of Economic Statistics 9(2): 74–92.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chao, Hsiang-Ke. 2009. Representation and structure in economics: The methodology of econometric models of the consumption function. London/New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Christ, Carl F. 1994. The Cowles Commission’s contributions to econometrics at Chicago, 1939–1955. Journal of Economic Literature 32(1): 30–59.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frisch, Ragnar. 1933a. Editorial. Econometrica 1: 1–4.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frisch, Ragnar. 1933b. Propagation problems and impulse problems in dynamic economics. In Economic essays in honour of Gustav Cassel, 171–205. London: Allen & Unwin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frisch, Ragnar. 1948. Repercussion studies at Oslo. The American Economic Review 38(3): 367–372.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frisch, Ragnar. 1995. Statistical versus theoretical relations in economic macrodynamics. In The foundations of econometric analysis, ed. D. Hendry and M.S. Morgan, 407–419. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Girshick, M.A., and Trygve Haavelmo. 1953. Statistical analysis of the demand for food: Examples of simultaneous estimation of structural equations. In Studies in econometric method, Cowles commission monograph 14, ed. W.C. Hood and T.C. Koopmans, 92–111. New York: Wiley. First published in 1947 in Econometrica 15.2: 79–110.

    Google Scholar 

  • Haavelmo, Trygve. 1940. The inadequacy of testing dynamic theory by comparing theoretical solutions and observed cycles. Econometrica 8: 312–321.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haavelmo, Trygve. 1944. The probability approach in econometrics. Supplement to Econometrica 12: 1–115.

    Google Scholar 

  • Haavelmo, Trygve. 1950. Remarks on Frisch’s confluence analysis and its use in econometrics. In Statistical inference in dynamic economic models, Cowles commission monograph 10, ed. T.C. Koopmans, 258–265. New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hanau, Arthur. 1928. Die Prognose der Schweinepreise, Vierteljahrshefte zur Konjunkturforschung, Sonderheft Berlin: Institut für Konjunkturforschung 7.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hendry, David F., and Mary S. Morgan (eds.). 1995. The foundations of econometric analysis. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hoover, Kevin D. 1994. Econometrics as observation: The Lucas critique and the nature of econometric inference. Journal of Economic Methodology 1(1): 65–80.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kalecki, Michal. 1935. A macrodynamic theory of business cycles. Econometrica 3: 327–344.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Karsten, Karl G. 1924. The theory of quadrature in economics. Journal of the American Statistical Association 19: 14–27.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Karsten, K.G. 1926. The Harvard business indexes – A new interpretation. Journal of the American Statistical Association 21: 399–418.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keynes, John Maynard. 1939. Professor Tinbergen’s method. The Economic Journal 49(195): 558–568.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Koopmans, Tjalling C., Herman Rubin, and Roy B. Leipnik. 1950. Measuring the equation systems of dynamic economics. In Statistical inference in dynamic economic models, Cowles commission monograph 10, ed. T.C. Koopmans, 53–237. New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Magnus, Jan R., and Mary S. Morgan. 1987. The ET interview: Professor J. Tinbergen. Econometric Theory 3: 117–142.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marschak, Jacob. 1934. The meeting of the econometric society in Leyden, September–October, 1933. Econometrica 2: 187–203.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morgan, Mary S. 1990. The history of econometric ideas. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Tinbergen, Jan. 1927. Over de Mathematies-Statistiese Methoden voor Konjunktuuronderzoek. De Economist 11: 711–723.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tinbergen, Jan. 1928. Opmerkingen over Ruilteorie. Socialistische Gids 13(5): 431–445, 13.6: 539–548.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tinbergen, Jan. 1931. Ein Schiffbauzyklus? Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv 34(2): 152–164.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tinbergen, Jan. 1933a. L’Utilisation des Équations Fonctionnelles et des Nombres Complexes Dans les Recherches Économiques. Econometrica 1: 36–51.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tinbergen, Jan. 1933b. Statistiek en Wiskunde in Dienst van het Konjunktuuronderzoek. Amsterdam: Arbeiderspers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tinbergen, Jan. 1935. Annual survey: Suggestions on quantitative business cycle theory. Econometrica 3(3): 241–308.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tinbergen, Jan. 1939a. Statistical testing of business-cycle theories I; a method and its application to investment activity. Geneva: League of Nations.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tinbergen, Jan. 1939b. Statistical testing of business-cycle theories II; business cycles in the United States of America. Geneva: League of Nations.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Marcel Boumans .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2013 Springer Science+Business Media Dordrecht

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Boumans, M. (2013). The Regrettable Loss of Mathematical Molding in Econometrics. In: Chao, HK., Chen, ST., Millstein, R. (eds) Mechanism and Causality in Biology and Economics. History, Philosophy and Theory of the Life Sciences, vol 3. Springer, Dordrecht. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-94-007-2454-9_4

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics