Skip to main content
  • 957 Accesses

Abstract

Initially contracts have been considered as a mechanism to save on transaction costs. However, over time they have come to be regarded a result of the need to share risks. Risks can be either exogenous to the contracting parties or generated by them (endogenous). In particular, information asymmetry creates adverse selection and exogenous randomness while endogenous randomness is due to moral hazard. The principal agent models essentially contain a formal characterization of risk sharing in contracts towards its efficiency. There is an acknowledgement that such sharing results in a propensity to take up more risky transactions and spread them to more individuals in various forms. Mature individuals are expected to regulate their activities and contain risks within acceptable bounds. Individual greed may however lead to systemic risks which are beyond their control. Efficient regulation must be conceptualized to move the system back to stability.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

eBook
USD 16.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    The recent book by Bolton and Dewatripont (2005) contains details of contract design. However, they did not deal with the details of the principal agent models.

  2. 2.

    Jensen and Meckling (1976) is the most influential specification of agency costs. On the other hand, Williamson (1988) contains a succinct exposition of the distinctions between transaction costs and agency costs.

  3. 3.

    Note that vertical integration and circumventing the market lead to contracts within the firm. The labor market literature predominantly deals with this. Contracts with agents outside the firm, e.g., subcontractors, franchisees etc., is equally dominant. The first set of studies is closer to the transaction cost argument of Coase while the latter are more concerned about agency costs. They also differ with respect to the duration of contracts. The present study concentrates mostly on the second type of contracts.

  4. 4.

    The literature on mechanisms design is rather extensive. Many useful concepts of efficient contract design are discernible. The principal agent model is one among the several alternatives. To the extent I am aware of it no formal comparisons, among the alternatives, has been attempted so far. The basic reason is that the econometric problems involved in such an enterprise are formidable. The reader may refer to Masten and Saussier (2002) for a review of econometric studies dealing with the choice of markets versus contracts.

  5. 5.

    Though somewhat dated, the early exposition by Rees (1985a, b) contains very useful insights about the principal agent models.

  6. 6.

    Two aspects of this specification should be noted clearly. First, that the principal would spend more to achieve the same result. It is not possible to justify delegation to the agent otherwise. Second, the cost reduction y must exceed y 2/2δ. For, otherwise, there is no point in entrusting the job to the agent.

  7. 7.

    No specific effort, to categorize randomness as external to the contracting individuals or endogenous to their functions, has been discernible expect when some specific details have been incorporated.

  8. 8.

    As the model implies σ 2 is a constant independent of p. Hence, it would be necessary to clarify the form that this improvement takes. An obvious approach is to make σ 2 a function of p.

  9. 9.

    Two aspects of this specification should be noted clearly. First, that the principal would spend more to achieve the same result. It is not possible to justify delegation to the agent otherwise. Second, the cost reduction y must exceed y 2/2δ. For, otherwise, there is no point in entrusting the job to the agent.

  10. 10.

    In this formulation u may be purely exogenous. In such a case, an agent who is made to share risk feels that he is being punished for something he did not do. There is then a possibility that he will reduce y if σ 2 increases. This was noted in Borenstein et al. (2007). Alternatively, Baker (2006) suggested the following. The agent may use more resources and incur greater costs, given his risk aversion, in order to be sure that he may deliver the promised output. This can also give rise to the possibility that y depends on λ and/or σ 2. However, note that in this formulation it is independent of σ 2 ex ante given p. Ex post p will depend on σ 2 and hence the observed y is not independent of σ 2. By way of contrast, based on some experimental evidence, Sloof and vanPragg (2008) noted that y does not depend on σ 2 even ex post. Some basic adaptations will be necessary to replicate this result in principal agent models of this vintage.

  11. 11.

    Clearly, delegation would be beneficial whenever

    $$ \varepsilon <{\delta}^2/\left(\delta +2\lambda {\sigma}^2\right) $$
  12. 12.

    It would be reasonable to suggest that the labels principal and the agent are for analytical convenience only. Their functional roles determine the nature of the contract.

  13. 13.

    In the standard model a more efficient agent reduces the costs of production as in this case but the costs due to his risk aversion do not depend on y or δ a priori.

  14. 14.

    Cooper and Ross (1985), Emons (1988), and Dybvig and Lutz (1993) acknowledged that the consumers can adjust the care with which they use the product. Thus, the consumers can exert some influence on the failure of the product depending on the way they use it. The issue is this. What determines the adjustments in δ? λσ 2 is surely one of the determinants. Emons (1988) argued that p, viz., the warranty offered, may itself determine the choice of δ. Similarly, following the argument of Murty and Blischke (2000), it can be argued that even the firm makes adjustments in several characteristics of its product when it recognizes the pertinent dimensions of consumer risk aversion. This may include the warranty and the σ 2 itself. We will not consider these alternatives in detail here.

  15. 15.

    This argument holds only for a given λσ 2. In such a case the resulting p is the minimum rather than a maximum. There will be a simultaneous choice of λσ 2 that the agent would exhibit. This is entirely plausible if σ 2 is a result of the agent’s action instead of its being fixed exogenously.

  16. 16.

    Jullien et al. (1999) pointed out that the costs to the agent, of making such adjustments in his efficiency levels, will not be negligible. Hence, he must weigh the advantages due to an increase in p against such costs. This may be the primary reason why we do not expect η > 1 in practice. Secondly, there may be limits on the extent to which he would be willing to take increased risk. In the limit, even the maximum p may not be attainable.

  17. 17.

    An increase in C beyond 2 will increase the value of the contract to the agent. However, it would be realistic to expect that the principal wishes to maintain as large a share of output as the agent will concede. Note that any C ≥ 2 will be acceptable to both of them if both of them maximize their respective value and disregard the share of output.

References

  • Agarwal RM (2007) Role of risk sharing and transaction costs in contract choice: theory and evidence from groundwater contracts. J Econ Behav Organ 63:475–496

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baker R (2006) Risk aversion in maintenance: overmaintenance and the principal agent problem. IMA J Manag Math 17:99–113

    Article  MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Bolton P, Dewatripont M (2005) Contract theory. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Borenstein S, Busse M, Kellogg R (2007) Principal agent incentives, excess caution, and market inefficiency: evidence from utility regulation. NBER working paper 13679. Available at www.nber.org/papers/w13679

  • Coase RH (1937) The nature of the firm. Economica 4:386–405

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coase RH (1960) The problem of social cost. J Law Econ 3:1–44

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cooper R, Ross TW (1985) Product warranties and double moral hazard. Rand J Econ 16:103–113

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Datta PK, Radner R (1994) Optimal principal agent contracts for a class of incentive schemes: a characterization and the rate of approach to efficiency. Econ Theory 4:483–503

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dybvig PH, Lutz NA (1993) Warranties, durability and maintenance: two-sided moral hazard in a continuous time model. Rev Econ Stud 60:575–597

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Emons W (1988) Warranties, moral hazard and the lemons problem. J Econ Theory 46:16–33

    Article  MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Ferrall C, Shearer R (1999) Incentives and transaction costs within the firm: estimating an agency model using payroll records. Rev Econ Stud 66:309–338

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Holmstrom B (1979) Moral hazard and observability. Bell J Econ 10:74–91

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jensen MC, Meckling WH (1976) Theory of the firm: managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure. J Financ Econ 3:305–360

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jullien B, Salanie B, Salanie F (1999) Should more risk averse agents exert more effort? Geneva Pap Risk Insur Theory 24:19–28

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaufman PJ, Lafontaine F (1994) Costs of control: the sources of economic rents for McDonald’s franchisees. J Law Econ 37:417–454

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kawasaki S, McMillan J (1987) The design of contracts: evidence from Japanese subcontracting. J Jpn Int Econ 1:327–349

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Lafontaine F (1992) Agency theory and franchising: some empirical results. Rand J Econ 23:263–283

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Masten SE, Saussier S (2002) Econometrics of contracts: an assessment of developments in the empirical literature on contracting. In: Brousseau E, Glachant JM (eds) The economics of contracts. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Mirrlees J (1974) Notes on welfare economics, information, and uncertainty. In: Balch M, McFadden D, Wu S (eds) Essays in economic behavior under uncertainty. North Holland, Amsterdam

    Google Scholar 

  • Murty DNP, Blischke WR (2000) Strategic warranty management: a life-cycle approach. IEEE Trans Eng Manag 47:40–54

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nichiols S (1983) Agency contracts, institutional mode, and the transition to foreign direct investment by British manufacturing multinationals before 1939. J Econ Hist 43:675–686

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rees R (1985a) The theory of principal and agent: part 1. Bull Econ Res 37:3–26

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rees R (1985b) The theory of principal and agent: part 2. Bull Econ Res 37:75–95

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sloof R, vanPragg CM (2008) Performance measurement, expectancy, and agency theory: an experimental study. J Econ Behav Organ 67:794–809

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Svejner J, Smith SC (1984) The economics of joint ventures in less developed countries. Q J Econ 99:149–167

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Williamson OE (1988) Corporate finance and corporate governance. J Financ 43:567–591

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2016 Springer India

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Rao, T.V.S.R. (2016). Introduction. In: Risk Sharing, Risk Spreading and Efficient Regulation. Springer, New Delhi. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-81-322-2562-1_1

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics