Irrigation Institutions and the Games Irrigators Play: Rule Enforcement Without Guards

  • Franz Weissing
  • Elinor Ostrom
Chapter

Abstract

This is the first of three efforts examining how irrigation institutions affect equilibrium stealing and enforcement rates. In this chapter, we examine rule—following and rule—enforcement rates of behavior adopted by irrigators on systems where rules are self—enforced rather than enforced by formal guards. To do this, we assume that irrigators rotate into the position of a turntaker. When in the position of a turntaker, they choose between taking a legal amount of water and taking more water than authorized (stealing). The other irrigators are turnwaiters who must decide whether to expend resources to monitor the behavior of the turntaker or not. In all our models, we find no combination of parameters where the rate of stealing by the turntaker falls to zero. In other words, there is always some stealing going on.

We give a complete equilibrium analysis for the situation where all irrigators have the same payoffs, monitoring efficiencies, and norms of behavior. Then, we examine how stealing and monitoring rates are affected by changes in parameters including: number of irrigators. cost of monitoring, detection probabilities, relative benefits of stealing, losses felt when stealing occurs, and the reward for successful discovery of a stealing event. Our final analysis addresses how the introduction of asymmetries in payoffs, monitoring efficiencies, and/or norms of behavior affects the distribution of equilibrium outcomes. One consequence of asymmetry is that there is no longer a unique Nash equilibrium. We find both paradoxical and non—paradoxical equilibria. In the paradoxical equilibria, just those turnwaiters monitor less who are inherently in a better position to monitor. In the non—paradoxical equilibria, one class of turnwaiters sticks to a pure strategy while the turntaker adjusts his stealing rate to the cost—benefit ratio of the others who are monitoring at an intermediate rate.

Several of our results are counterintuitive at first sight and reflect the interactive nature of the situation and the interdependence of the players. Our findings also contribute to a more general understanding of the relative weight of ‘primary’ and ‘secondary’ interaction effects in a mixed—strategy context.

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  1. Ascher, W. and R. Healy (1990): Natural Resource Policy Making in Developing Countries. Durham, North Carolina: Duke Univ. Press.Google Scholar
  2. Asian Development Bank (1973): Regional Workshop on Irrigation Water Management. Manila, Phillippines: Asian Development Bank.Google Scholar
  3. Bianco, W.T., P.T. Ordeshook, and G. Tsebelis (1990): Crime and Punishment: Are One—Shot, Two—Person Games Enough? American Political Science Review 84: 569–586.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Bogardi, I. and F. Szidarovszky (1976): Application of Game Theory in Water Management. Applied Mathematical Modelling 1: 16–20.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Bromley, D.W. (1982): Improving Irrigated Agriculture: Institutional Reform and the Small Farmer. Washington, D.C.: World Bank Staff Working Paper, No. 531.Google Scholar
  6. Cernea, M.M (1985): Putting People First. Sociological Variables in Rural Development. New York: Oxford Univ. Press.Google Scholar
  7. Chambers, R. (1980): Basic Concepts in the Organization of Irrigation. In: E.W. Coward Jr. (ed.): Irrigation and Agricultural Developement in Asia. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell Univ. press, pp. 2288Google Scholar
  8. Chambers, R. and I.D. Carruthers (1986): Rapid Appraisal to Improve Canal Irrigation Performance: Experience and Options. IIMI Research Paper No. 3. Digan Village, Sri Lanka: International Irrigation Managment Institute.Google Scholar
  9. Colmey, J.L. (1988): Irrigated Non—Rice Crops: Asia’s Untapped Resource. IIMI Review 2: 3–7.Google Scholar
  10. Corey, A.T. (1986): Control of Water Within Farm Turnouts in Sri Lanka. Proceedings of a Workshop on Water Managment in Sri Lanka. Documentation Series No. 10. Colombo: Agrarian Research and Training Institute.Google Scholar
  11. Coward, E.W. Jr. (1980): Management Themes in Community Irrigation Systems. In: E.W. Coward Jr.(ed.): Irrigation and Agricultural Development in Asia. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell Univ. Press, pp. 15–27.Google Scholar
  12. Coward, E.W. Jr. (1985): Technical and Social Change in Currently Irrigated Regions: Rules, Roles and Rehabilitation. In: M.M. Cernea (ed.): Putting People First. Sociological Variables in Rural Development. New York: Oxford Univ. Press. pp. 27–51.Google Scholar
  13. Crawford V.P. (1985): Learning Behavior and Mixed Strategy Nash Equilibria. J. Economic Behay. Organis. 6: 69–78.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Cross, J.G. (1983): A Theory of Adaptive Economic Behavior. Cambridge, England: Cambridge Univ. Press.Google Scholar
  15. de los Reyes, R.P. (1980): Managing Communal Gravity Systems. Farmers’ Approaches and Implications for Program Planning. Quezon City, Phillippines: Institute of Phillippine Culture.Google Scholar
  16. Elster, J. (1989): The Cement of Society. A Study of Social Order. Cambridge, England: Univ. of Cambridge Press.Google Scholar
  17. Eshel, I. (1982): Evolutionarily Stable Strategies and Viability Selection in Mendelian Populations. Theoretical Population Biology 22: 204–217.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  18. Eshel, Ì., and E. Akin (1983): Coevolutionary Instability of Mixed Nash Solutions. J. Mathem. Biology 18: 123–133.Google Scholar
  19. Fernea, R.A. (1970): Shakh and Effendi: Changing Patterns of Authority Among the El Shabana of Southern Iraq. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Univ. Press.Google Scholar
  20. Freeman, D.M., and M.L. Lowdermilk (1985): Middle—level Organizational Linkages in Irrigation Projects. In: M.M. Cernea (ed.): Putting People First. Sociological Variables in Rural Development. New York: Oxford Univ. Press. pp. 91–118.Google Scholar
  21. Friedman, D. (1989): Evolutionary Economic Games. Working Paper.Google Scholar
  22. Friedman, J.W., and R.W. Rosenthal (1986): A Positive Approach to Non—Cooperative Games. J. Econom. Behay. Organiz. 7: 235–251.Google Scholar
  23. Glick, T.F. (1970): Irrigation and Society in Medieval Valencia. Cambridge, Ms.: The Belknap Press of Harvard Univ. Press.Google Scholar
  24. Hansen, R.G., and W.F. Samuelson (1988): Evolution in Economic Games. J. Econom. Behay. Organiz. 10: 315–338.Google Scholar
  25. Harriss J.C. (1977): Problems of Water Management in Hambantota District. In: B.H. Farmer (ed.): Green Revolution? Technology and Change in Rice Growing Areas of Tamil Nadu and Sri Lanka. New York: MacMillan, pp. 364–376.Google Scholar
  26. Harriss, J.C. (1984): Social Organisation and Irrigation: Ideology, Planning, and Practice in Sri Lanka’s Settlement Schemes. In: T.P. Bayliss—Smith and S. Wanmali (eds.): Understanding Green Revolutions. Cambridge, England: Cambridge Univ. Press, pp. 315–338.Google Scholar
  27. Harsanyi, J.C. (1977): Rational Behavior and Bargaining Equilibrium in Games and Social Situations. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  28. Harsanyi, J.C. and R. Selten (1988): A General Theory of Equilibrium Selection in Games. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press.Google Scholar
  29. Hart, H.C. (1978): Anarchy, Paternalism, or Collective Responsibility Under the Canals? Economic and Political Weekly 13 (52): Al25—A134.Google Scholar
  30. Heaney, J.P. and R.E. Dickinson (1982): Methods for Apportioning the Cost of a Water Resource Project. Water Resources Research 18: 476–482.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  31. Hechter, M. (1987): Principles of Group Solidarity. Berkeley, CA: Univ. of California Press.Google Scholar
  32. Hofbauer, J., and K. Sigmund (1988): The Theory of Evolution and Dynamical Systems. Cambridge: Cambridge Univ. Press.Google Scholar
  33. Holler, M.J. (1990): The Unprofitability of Mixed—Strategy Equilibria in Two—Person Games. Economics Letters 32: 319–323.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  34. International Bank for Reconstruction and Development (IBRD) (1985): Tenth Annual Review of Project Performance Audit Results. Washington, D.C.: World Bank, Operations Evaluation Department.Google Scholar
  35. Levine, G. (1980): The Relationship of Design, Operation, and Management. In: E.W. Coward, Jr. (ed.): Irrigation and Agricultural Development in Asia. Ithaca: Cornell Univ. Press. pp. 51–64.Google Scholar
  36. Luce, R.D., and H. Raiffa (1957): Games and Decisions: Introduction and Critical Survey. New York: Wiley.Google Scholar
  37. Maass, A. and R.L. Anderson (1986): … and the Desert Shall Rejoice. Conflict, Growth, and Justice in Arid Environments. Malabar, Fl.: Krieger Publ. Co.Google Scholar
  38. Maynard Smith, J. (1982): Evolution and the Theory of Games. Cambridge, England: Cambridge Univ. Press.Google Scholar
  39. Mehra, S. (1981): Instability in Indian Agriculture in the Context of the New Technology. Washington, D.C.: Intern. Food Policy Research Institution. Research Report No. 25.Google Scholar
  40. Nachbar, J. (1990): ‘Evolutionary’ Selection Dynamics in Games: Convergence and Limit Properties. to appear in: Intern. J. Game Theory.Google Scholar
  41. Nash, J.F. (1950): Equilibrium Points in n—Person Games. Proc. Nat. Acad. Sci. USA 36: 48–49.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  42. Nash, J.F. (1951): Non—Cooperative Games. Annals of Mathematics 54: 286–295.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  43. Negri, D.H. (1989): The Common Property Aquifer as a Differential Game. Water Resources Research 25: 9–15.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  44. Nepal Irrigation Research Project (1983): Sunduwari Irrigation System (Badichaur, Surkhet). Kathmandu, Nepal: Nepal Irrigation Research Project, mimeo.Google Scholar
  45. Netting, R. (1974): In: T.E. Downing and M. Gibson (eds): Irrigation’s Impact on Society. Tucson, Arizona: The University of Arizona Press.Google Scholar
  46. O’Neill, B. (1987): Nonmetric Test of the Minimax Theory of Two—Person Zerosum Games. Proc. Nat. Acad. Sci. USA 84: 2106–2109.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  47. Pressman, J.L. and A. Wildaysky (1973): Implementation. Berkeley, California: Univ. of California Press.Google Scholar
  48. Rasmusen, E. (1989): Games and Information. An Introduction to Game Theory. Oxford, England: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
  49. Rogers, P. (1969): A Game Theory Approach to the Problems of International River Basins. Water Resources Research 5: 749–760.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  50. Selten, R. (1983): Evolutionary Stability in Extensive Two—Person Games. Mathem. Social Sciences 5: 269–363.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  51. Selten, R. (1991): Anticipatory Learning in Two—Person Games. To appear in: R. Selten (ed.): Game Equilibrium Models. Vol. 1: Evolution and Gaine Dynamics. Berlin, Heidelberg, New York: Springer—Verlag.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  52. Spooner, B. (1974): Irrigation and Society. The Iranian Plateau. In: T.E. Downing and M. Gibson (eds): Irrigation’s Impact on Society. Tucson, Arizona: The University of Arizona Press.Google Scholar
  53. Straffin, P.D. and J.P. Heaney (1981): Game Theory and the Tennessee Valley Authority. Intern. J. Game Theory 10: 35–43CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  54. Tang, S.Y. (1989): Institutions and Collective Action in Irrigation Systems. Bloomington, Indiana: Indiana University, Department of Political Science. Ph.D. dissertation.Google Scholar
  55. Tsebelis, G. (1989): The Abuse of Probability in Political Analysis: The Robinson Crusoe Fallacy. American Political Science Review 83: 77–91.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  56. Tsebelis, G. (1990a): Penalty Has No Impact on Crime: A Game—Theoretical Analysis. Rationality and Society 2: 255–286.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  57. Tsebelis, G. (1990b): The Effect of Fines on Regulated Industries: Game Theory vs. Decision Theory. Journal of Theoretical Politics, forthcoming.Google Scholar
  58. Uphoff, N. (1985): Fitting Projects to People. In: M.M Cemea (ed.): Putting People First. Sociological Variables in Rural Development. New York: Oxford University Press, pp. 359–398.Google Scholar
  59. USAID (1983): Irrigation Assistance to Developing Countries Should Require Stronger Commitments to Operation and Maintenance. Washington, D.C.: General Accounting Office.Google Scholar
  60. van Damme, E. (1983): Refinements of the Nash Equilibrium Concept. Berlin: Springer—Verlag.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  61. van Damme, E. (1987): Stability and Perfection of Nash Equilibrium. Berlin: Springer—Verlag.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  62. von Neumann, J. and O. Morgenstern (1944): The Theory of Games and Economic Behavior. New York: Wiley.Google Scholar
  63. Wade, R. (1990): On the ‘Technical’ Causes of Irrigation Hoarding Behavior, or Why Irrigators Keep Interfering in the Main System. In: R.K. Sampath (ed.): Institutional Aspects of Canal Irrigation. Fort Collins, Colorado: Colorado State University, forthcoming.Google Scholar
  64. Walker, H.H. (1983): Determinants for the Organisation of Irrigation Projects. In: Man and Technology in Irrigated Agriculture. Irrigation Symposium, 1982. Hamburg: Verlag Paul Parey, pp. 19–36.Google Scholar
  65. Weissing, F. (1983): Populationsgenetische Grundlagen der Evolutionären Spieltheorie. Bielefeld: Materialien zur Mathematisierung der Einzelwissenschaften, No. 41 and No 42.Google Scholar
  66. Weissing, F. (1991): Evolutionary Stability and Dynamic Stability in a Class of Evolutionary Normal Form Games. To appear in: R. Selten (ed.): Game Equilibrium Models. Vol 1: Evolution and Game Dynamics. Berlin: Springer—Verlag.Google Scholar
  67. Wittman, D. (1985): Counter—intuitive Results in Game Theory. European Journal of Political Economy 1: 77–89.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  68. Young, H.P., N. Okada, and T. Hashimoto (1982): Cost Allocation in Water Resources Development. Water Resources Research 18: 463–475.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg 1991

Authors and Affiliations

  • Franz Weissing
  • Elinor Ostrom

There are no affiliations available

Personalised recommendations