Skip to main content

Non-Linear Dynamics and Chaos in Optimal Growth: A Constructive Exposition

  • Chapter
Book cover Optimization and Chaos

Part of the book series: Studies in Economic Theory ((ECON.THEORY,volume 11))

Abstract

In the recent literature, it has been demonstrated that optimal capital accumulation may be chaotic; see Boldrin and Montrucchio (1986) , and Deneckere and Pelikan (1986). 1 This finding indicates, as Scheinkman (1990) discusses, that the deterministic equilibrium model of a dynamic economy may explain various complex dynamic behaviors of economic variables, and, in fact, search for such explanations has already begun (see Brock, 1986, and Scheinkman and LeBaron, 1989, for example) . In the existing literature, however, not much has yet been revealed with respect to the circumstances under which optimal accumulation exhibits complex non-linear dynamics. In particular, it has not yet been known whether or not chaotic optimal accumulation may appear in the case in which future utilities are discounted not so strongly.2

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 129.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  1. These studies are followed by the recent work of Boldrin and Deneckere (1990) and Majumdar and Mitra (Chapter 3). For earlier treatments of chaotic economic behaviors, see Benhabib and Day (1982), Day (1982) and Grandmont (1985), the models of which are not of optimal growth.

    Google Scholar 

  2. It has been known that if, given a technology and a period-wise preference, the discounting of future utilities is sufficiently weak, the classical turnpike result holds, i.e., the optimal paths converges to a stationary state; see Cass and Shell (1976), Scheinkman (1976), Brock and Scheinkman (1976) and McKenzie (1983). Sorger (1990), moreover, demonstrates the existence of an upper bound of discount factors with which a given trajectory is a solution to an optimal growth model. These results, however, do not exclude the possibility that for any given degree of the discounting of future utilities, there may be a technology and a period-wise preference that result in chaotic optimal dynamics.

    Google Scholar 

  3. See Deneckere and Pelikan (1986) and Boldrin and Montrucchio (1986b) .

    Google Scholar 

  4. Boldrin and Montrucchio (1986b) discuss the possibility of chaotic optimal dynamics for values of p up to ρ = 0.25; see also Boldrin and Deneckere (1990), which focuses on topological chaos. As is well-known, topological chaos is a weaker form of chaotic dynamics (see Section 3 for an explanation).

    Google Scholar 

  5. Deneckere and Pelikan (1986), in contrast, assume that one sector has a Cobb-Douglas production function and that the other sector has a Leontief production function. In this case, a factor intensity reversal occurs.

    Google Scholar 

  6. Benhabib and Nishimura (1985) demonstrates that if and only if the sign of the cross partial derivative of a reduced form utility function is negative, the optimal transition function is downard sloping. (This result can be derived as a special case of the results obtained by Topkis (1978) and Marshall and Olkin (1979).) Because the existence of a capital intensive consumption good sector implies a negative cross partial derivative, the transition function monotone dressing. Because Benhabib and Nishimura (1985) assumes differentiability, the result of that study does not directly apply to our case, which is nondifferentiable. However, a more or less similar relationship appears in our setting, as is shown below.

    Google Scholar 

  7. Boldrin and Deneckere (1990) discusses use of the boundary imposed by the limit of capital depreciation.

    Google Scholar 

  8. 0n the differentiability of an optimal transition function, see Araujo (1991), Boldrin and Montrucchio (1989) and Santos (1991).

    Google Scholar 

  9. See Section 3 for precise definitions.

    Google Scholar 

  10. The existence of cyclical optimal paths plays important roles in Deneckere and Pelikan (1986), and Boldrin and Deneckere (1990) as well. Those studies characterize a cyclical optimal path by the Euler equation. In contrast, we characterize it by support prices. This difference is due to the fact we focus on non-interior solutions in a non-differentiable model while the existing studies consider interior solutions in a differentiable model.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2000 Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Nishimura, K., Yano, M. (2000). Non-Linear Dynamics and Chaos in Optimal Growth: A Constructive Exposition. In: Optimization and Chaos. Studies in Economic Theory, vol 11. Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-662-04060-7_8

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-662-04060-7_8

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-642-08636-6

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-662-04060-7

  • eBook Packages: Springer Book Archive

Publish with us

Policies and ethics