Advertisement

Communication Norms and the Collective Cognitive Performance of “Invisible Colleges”

Conference paper

Abstract

Scientific research communities may be studied as social networks within which ideas or statements circulate, acquire validity as reliable knowledge, and are recombined to generate further new ideas. Social networks also form the locus for the transmission of tacit knowledge and skills requisite to the interpretation and operationalization of scientific statements. These extensive, yet informal structures of inter-personal knowledge-transactions have been referred to as constituting “invisible colleges”. This paper develops an abstract and highly stylized account of the communications structure of an invisible college, and examines its collective epistemological performance by employing concepts and results from Markov random field theory.

Keywords

Social Network Tacit Knowledge Local Network Markov Random Field Scientific Statement 
These keywords were added by machine and not by the authors. This process is experimental and the keywords may be updated as the learning algorithm improves.

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  1. Adler, C. G. and B. Coulter (1978), “Galileo and the Tower of Pisa Experiment”, American Journal of Physics, 46: 199–201.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Alba, R. (1973), “A graph-theoretic definition of a sociometric clique”, Journal of Mathematical Sociology, Vol. 1.Google Scholar
  3. Anderlini, L., and A. Ianni (1995), “Path dependence and learning from neighbours”, forthcoming in Games and Economic Behavior.Google Scholar
  4. Arora, A., P.A. David and A. Gambardella (1997), “Reputation and competence in publicly funded science: estimating the effects on research group productivity”. (A revised version of this paper presented at the National Bureau of Economic Research Productivity Workshop, is fothcoming in Annales d’Economie et de Statistiques, Numero Exceptionelle, ed. J. Mairesse.Google Scholar
  5. Arora, A., and A. Gambardella (1998), “Public policy towards science: picking stars or spreading the wealth?”, forthcoming in Revue d’Economie Industrielle Google Scholar
  6. Arora, A., and A. Gambardella (1994), “The changing technology of technological change: general and abstract knowledge and the division of innovative labour”, Research Policy 23, 523–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. Arrow, K.J. (1962), “Economic welfare and the allocation of resources for inventions”, in R.R. Nelson (ed.), The rate and direction of inventive activity: economic and social factors ( Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press ).Google Scholar
  8. Arrow, K.J. (1971), “Political and economic evaluation of social effects and externalities”, in M. Intrilligator (ed.), Frontiers of quantitative economics, Contributions to Economic Analysis No. 71 ( Amsterdam: North-Holland ).Google Scholar
  9. Bacharach, M., D. Gambetta et al. (1994), “The economics of salience: A research proposal”, Unpublished paper, Oxford Institute of Economics and Statistics.Google Scholar
  10. Bala, V., and S. Goyal (1995), “Learning from neighbors”, Econometric Institute Report 9549, Erasmus University, Rotterdam, September.Google Scholar
  11. Barnes, B. (1974), Scientific Knowledge and Sociological Theory, London: Routledge and Kegan Paul.Google Scholar
  12. Barnes, B. (1977), Interests and the Growth of Knowledge, London: Routledge and Kegan Paul.Google Scholar
  13. Bloor, D. (1976), Knowledge and Social Imagery, London: Routledge & Kegan Paul.Google Scholar
  14. Blume, L.E. (1993), “The statistical mechanics of strategic interaction”, Games and Economic Behavior, 4: 378–424.Google Scholar
  15. Bollobâs, M. (1979), Graph Theory: An Introductory Course. New York: Springer-Verlag.Google Scholar
  16. Callon, M. (1995) “Four models for the dynamics of science”, in S. Jasanoff, G.E. Markle, J.C. Petersen and T. Pinch (eds), Handbook of science and technology studies ( London: Sage Publications ).Google Scholar
  17. Callon, M., and J.-P. Courtial (1989), Co-word analysis: a tool for the evaluation of public research policy ( Paris: Ecole Nationale Supérieure des Mines).Google Scholar
  18. Campbell, D.T. (1965), “Variation and selective retention in socio-cultural evolution”, in H.R. Barringer, G.I. Blanksten and R.W. Mack (eds), Social change in developing areas ( Cambridge, MA: Schenkman Press ).Google Scholar
  19. Campbell, D.T. (1974), “Evolutionary epistemology”, in P.A. Schilpp (ed.), The philosophy of Karl R. Popper ( LaSalle: Open Court ).Google Scholar
  20. Campbell, D. T. (1994), “The Social Psychology of Scientific Validity: An Epistemological Perspective and a Personalized History”, Ch.2, in The Social Psychology of Science, New York: The Guilford Press.Google Scholar
  21. Caudill, Maureen and Charles Butler (1990), Naturally intelligent systems ( Cambridge, MA: MIT Press).Google Scholar
  22. Clifford, P., and A. Sudbury (1973), “A model for spatial conflict”, Biometrika 60, 581–8.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. Cole, J. and S. Cole (1973), Social Stratification in Science, Chicago: Chicago University Press.Google Scholar
  24. Cole, S. (1978), “Scientific Reward Systems: A Comparative Analysis”, in R. A. Jones, ed., Research in Sociology of Knowledge, Sciences and Art, Greenwich, Conn.: JAI Press, pp. 167–190.Google Scholar
  25. Cole, S. and Cole J. (1967), “Scientific Output and Recognition”, American Sociological Review, 32:.377–390.Google Scholar
  26. Collins, H.M. (1974), “The TEA set: tacit knowledge and scientific networks”, Science studies, 4: 165–86.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  27. Cowan, R. and D. Foray (1996), “The Economics of Codification and the Diffusion of Knowledge”, Unpublished working paper: IMRI, University of Paris-Dauphine, ( March).Google Scholar
  28. Cox, J. T. (1989), “Expected percolation times for the voter model on a d-dimensional torus”, Annals of Probability, 17 (4): 1333–1366.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  29. Crane, D. (1965), “Scientists at Major and Minor Universities: A Study in Productivity and Recognition”, American Sociological Review, 30:.699–714.Google Scholar
  30. Dalle, J.-M. (1995), “Dynamiques d’adoption, coordination et diversite: la diffusion des standards technologiques”, Revue Économiques, (July).Google Scholar
  31. Dasgupta, P., and P.A. David (1987), “Information disclosure and the economics of science and technology”, in G. Feiwel (ed.), Arrow and the ascent of modern economic theory, New York: New York University Press.Google Scholar
  32. Dasgupta, P., and P.A. David (1988), “Priority, secrecy, patents and the economic organization of science and technology”, CEPR Publication No. 127, Stanford University (March).Google Scholar
  33. Dasgupta, P. and P.A. David (1994), “Toward a new economics of science”, Research Policy 23: 487–521.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  34. David, P.A. (1988), “Path-dependence: putting the past into the future of economics”, Institute for Mathematical Studies in the Social Sciences Technical Report No. 533, Stanford University, ( November ).Google Scholar
  35. David, P.A. (1993a), “Historical economics in the long run: some implications of path dependence”, in G.D. Snooks (ed.), Historical analysis in economics ( London: Routledge ).Google Scholar
  36. David, P.A. (1993b), “Path dependence and predictability in dynamic systems with local network externalities: a paradigm for historical economics”, in D. Foray and C. Freeman (eds), Technology and the wealth of nations ( London: Pinter Publishers ).Google Scholar
  37. David, P.A. (1994a), “Positive feedbacks and research productivity in science: reopening another black box”, in O. Grandstrand (ed), Economics of Technology ( Amsterdam: North-Holland ).Google Scholar
  38. David, P.A. (1994b), “Les standards des technologies de l’information, les normes de communication et l’État: un problème de biens publics”, Analyse économique des conventions, ed. A. Orléan ( Paris: Presses Universitaires de France).Google Scholar
  39. David, R. A. (1995), “Reputation and Agency in the Historical Emergence of the Institutions of `Open Science”’, Paper presented to the National Academy of Sciences Colloquium on the Economics of Science and Technology, held at the Beckman Center, U.C. Irvine, 2021 October 1995.Google Scholar
  40. David, P.A. (1996a), “Science reorganized? Post-modern visions of research and the curse of success”, in Measuring R&D Impact - Proceedings of the Second International Symposium on Research Funding, ( Ottawa: NSERC of Canada).Google Scholar
  41. David, P. A. and T. Flemming (1995 & 1996 ), “Communications, creativity and research network dynamics: An elementary economic model of scientific communities”, Paper presented to the International Conference on Creation and Transfer of Knowledge, held at Castelgandolfo (Rome), September 1995; revised for presentation to the All Souls College Seminar on the Economics of Information Diffusion, convened in Oxford, May 1996.Google Scholar
  42. David, P.A., and D. Foray (1993), “Percolation structures, Markov random fields and the economics of EDI standards diffusion”, in G. Pogorel (ed.), Global telecommunication strategies and technological change ( Amsterdam: Elsevier ).Google Scholar
  43. David, P.A., and D. Foray (1994), “Dynamics of competitive technology diffusion through local network structures: the case of EDI document standards”, in Evolutionary economics and chaos theory: new developments in technology studies, L. Leysendorff and R. van den Besselaar, eds. ( London: Pinter Publishers ).Google Scholar
  44. David, P.A., and D. Foray (1995), “Accessing and expanding the knowledge-base in science and technology”, STI Review -Science, Technology and Industry, 16, ( OECD: Paris ).Google Scholar
  45. David, R. A., D. Foray and J.-M. Dalle (1997), “Marshallian externalities and the emergence and spatial stability of technological enclaves”, forthcoming in Economics of Innovation and New Technologies, vol.6 (Special issue on “The Economics of Localized Technological Changes”, ed A. Antonelli).Google Scholar
  46. David, P.A., A. Geuna, and W.E. Steinmueller (1995), “Additionality as a principle of European R&D funding”, Report for the STOA programme of the European Parliament, MERIT Research Memorandum 2/95/012, Maastricht.Google Scholar
  47. David, P.A., and S. Greenstein (1990), “The economics of compatibility standards: an introduction to recent research”, Economics of Innovation and New Technology 1 (1 & 2), Fall 1990, 3–42.Google Scholar
  48. David, P. A., D. Mowery, and W.E. Steinmueller (1992), “Analyzing the payoffs from basic research”, Economics of Innovation and New Technology, Vol. 2, No. 4.Google Scholar
  49. David, R. A., and W. C. Sanderson (1997), “Making use of treacherous advice: cognitive learning, Bayesian adaptation and the tenacity of unreliable knowledge”, in Frontiers of the New Institutional Economics, J. V. C. Nye and J. N. Drobak, eds. ( San Diego, CA: Academic Press. )Google Scholar
  50. Ellison, G. (1993), “Learning, local interaction, and coordination”, Econometrica, 61: 1047–1071.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  51. Ellison, G., and D. Fudenberg (1995), “Word-of-mouth communication and social learning”, Quarterly Journal of Economics 110 (1): pp. 93–126.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  52. Feyerabend, R. (1975), Against Method ( London: Humanities Press).Google Scholar
  53. Franklin, A. (1986), The Neglect of Experiment ( Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  54. Fuller, S. (1994), “A Guide to the Philosophy and Sociology of Science for Social Psychology of Science”, Ch. 17 in The Social Psychology of Science, New York: The Guilford Press.Google Scholar
  55. Gambardella, A. (1994), Science and innovation, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  56. Geison, G. L. (1996) “Pasteur and the Culture Wars: An Exchange, New York Review of Books, XLII(6), April 4: pp. 68–69.Google Scholar
  57. Grimmett, G. (1989), Percolation ( New York: Springer Verlag).Google Scholar
  58. Hammersley, J.M., and D.J. Welsh (1980), “Percolation theory and its ramification”, Contemporary Physics 21 (6).Google Scholar
  59. Harding, S. (1976), Can Theories Be Refuted? (Dordrecht: D. Reidel).Google Scholar
  60. Harris, T.E. (1978), “Additive set-valued Markov processes and percolation methods”, Annals of Probability 6.Google Scholar
  61. Henderson, R., A. Jaffe and M. Trajtenberg (1995a), “Universities as source of commercial technology: a detailed analysis of university patenting 1965–1988”, National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 5068, March.Google Scholar
  62. Henderson, R., A. Jaffe and M. Trajtenberg (1995b), “The Bayh-Dole Act and trends in university patenting 1965–1988”, paper presented to the Conference on University Goals, Institutional Mechanisms and the `Industrial Transferability’ of Research, March (Stanford: Stanford Center for Economic Policy Research); revised August.Google Scholar
  63. Hirshleifer, J. (1971), “The private and social value of information and the reward for inventive activity”, American Economic Review 61, 561–74.Google Scholar
  64. Holley, R., and T. Liggett (1975), “Ergodic theorems for weakly interacting systems and the voter model”, Annals of Probability 3, 643–63.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  65. Hull„ D. (ed.) (1988), Science as a process ( Chicago: University of Chicago Press ).Google Scholar
  66. Imai, K. and Y. Baba (1989), “Systemic innovation and cross-border networks”, paper presented to the International Seminar on the Contributions of Science and Technology to Economic Growth, June (Paris: OECD Division of Science, Technology, and Industry).Google Scholar
  67. Jaffe, A.B., M. Trajtenberg and R. Henderson (1993), “Geographic localization of knowledge spillovers as evidenced by patent citations”, Quarterly Journal of Economics.Google Scholar
  68. Kindermann, R., and J.L. Snell (1980a), “On the relation between Markov random fields and social networks”, Journal of Mathematical Sociology 7.Google Scholar
  69. Kindermann, R., and J.L. Snell (1980b), Markov random fields and their applications: Contemporary mathematics, Vol. 1 (American Mathematical Society).Google Scholar
  70. Kirman, A. (1993), “Ants, Rationality and Recruitment”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 108: 137–156.Google Scholar
  71. Kirman, A., C. Oddou, and S. Weber (1986), “Stochastic Communication and Coalition Formation”, Econometrica, 54 (1): 129–138.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  72. Knorr-Cetina, K. (1981), The Manufacture of Knowledge: An Essay on the Constructivist and Contextual Nature of Science, Oxford: Pergamon Press.Google Scholar
  73. Kuhn, T. S. (1962/1970), The Structure of Scientific Revolutions, First/Second Edition (Chicago: University of Chicago Press).Google Scholar
  74. Lakatos, I. (1970), “Falsification and the methodology of scientific research programmes”, in I. Lakatos and A. Musgrave (eds), Criticism and the growth of knowledge ( Cambridge: Cambridge University Press ).Google Scholar
  75. Latour, B., and S. Woolgar (1979), Laboratory life ( Beverly Hills: Sage Publications).Google Scholar
  76. Leydesdorff, Loet (1995), The challenge of scientometrics: the development, measurement, and self-organization of scientific communities ( Leiden: DSWO Press).Google Scholar
  77. Luhmann, N. (1984), Soziale systeme. Grundrisz einer allgemeinen Theorie ( Frankfurt a.M.: Suhrkamp).Google Scholar
  78. Luhmann, N. (1990), Die Wissenschaft der Gesellschaft ( Frankfurt a.M.: Suhrkamp).Google Scholar
  79. Marschak, J. (1971), “The economics of information”, in M. Intrilligator (ed.), Frontiers of quantitative economics, Contributions to Economic Analysis No. 71 ( Amsterdam: North-Holland ).Google Scholar
  80. Merton, R.K. (1973), in N.W. Storer (ed.), The sociology of science: theoretical and empirical investigations ( Chicago: University of Chicago Press).Google Scholar
  81. Morris, S. (1996), “Strategic Behavior with General Local Interaction”, University of Pennsylvania Department of Economics Working Paper. March.Google Scholar
  82. Mulkay, M. (1979), Science and the Sociology of Knowledge, London: George Allen and Unwin.Google Scholar
  83. Narin, F. (1976), Evaluative bibliometrics (Cherry Hill, NJ: Computer Horizons, Inc.).Google Scholar
  84. Perutz, M.F. (1996), “Pasteur and the Culture Wars: An Exchange, New York Review of Books, XLII(6), April 4: pp. 68–69.Google Scholar
  85. Polanyi, M. (1966), The Tacit Dimension ( London: Routledge and Kegan Paul).Google Scholar
  86. Popper, K. R. (1959), Logic of scientific discovery ( London: Hutchinson).Google Scholar
  87. Popper, K. R. (1963), Conjectures and refutations (London: Routledge & Kegan Paul).Google Scholar
  88. Price, D. J. de Solla (1965), “Networks of scientific papers”, Science 149, 510–15.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  89. Price, D. J. de Solla (1986), Little science, big science and beyond ( New York: Columbia University Press).Google Scholar
  90. Quine, W. V. 0. (1953), “Two Dogmas of Empiricism”, in From A Logical Point of View, ( Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press).Google Scholar
  91. Quine, W. V. 0. (1962), “Carnap and logical truth”, in Logic and language: studies dedicated to Professor Rudolf Carnap on the occasion of his seventieth birthday ( Dordrecht: Reidel).Google Scholar
  92. Quine, W. V. 0. (1969), Ontological Relativity, New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
  93. Schelling, T. (1971), “Dynamic models of segregation”, Journal of Mathematical Sociology 1.Google Scholar
  94. Shadish, W. And S. Fuller, eds., The Social Psychology of Science,New York: The Guilford Press.Google Scholar
  95. Stephan, P. (1996), “The Economics of Science”, Journal of Economic Literature, XXXIV (3), September: 1199–1262.Google Scholar
  96. Trajtenberg, M., R. Henderson and A. B. Jaffe (1992), “Ivory tower versus corporate lab: an empirical study of basic research and appropriability”, National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 4146, August.Google Scholar
  97. Usher, Abbott Payson (1982), A History of Mechanical Invention, Revised Edition, New York: Dover Publications.Google Scholar
  98. van Rann, A.F.J., ed. (1988), Handbook of quantitative studies of science and technology ( Amsterdam: Elsevier ).Google Scholar
  99. Weitzman, M. L. (1995), “Recombinant Growth”, Harvard University Economics Department Working Paper. March.Google Scholar
  100. Worrall, J. (1976), “Thomas Young and the `Refutation’ of Newtonian Optics: A Case-study in the Interaction of Philosophy of Science and History of Science”, in Method and Appraisal in the Physical Sciences, ed. C. Howson, ( Cambridge: Cambridge University Press ).Google Scholar
  101. Ziman, J. (1984), An introduction to science studies: the philosophical and social aspects of science and technology ( Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  102. Zuckerman, H. (1977), The Scientific Elite: Nobel Laureates in the United States, New York: The Free Press.Google Scholar
  103. Zuckerman, H. and R. K. Merton (1971), “Institutionalization and Patterns of Evaluation in Science”, in R K. Merton,The sociology of science: theoretical and empirical investigations, N.W. Storer, ed., Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1973.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg 1998

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.All Souls CollegeOxford and Stanford UniversityUK

Personalised recommendations