Skip to main content

Max Weber and the Sociology of Organization

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Max Weber and the sociology of organization
  • 290 Accesses

Abstract

As has been shown, the sociology of organization developed primarily in the USA, from where it was imported to Germany primarily by Niklas Luhmann and Renate Mayntz from the 1960s onwards. One, if not the central, point of reference for early US organizational sociology is Max Weber’s sociology of rule. This is surprising in that Weber cannot easily be considered an organizational sociologist.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

eBook
USD 16.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 16.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    In his biography of Weber, Jürgen Kaube judges that the history of organizational sociology, “initiated by Weber, represents a single critique of his machine analogy and his picture of hierarchical control” (Kaube, 2014, p. 262). W. Richard Scott even judges that Max Weber’s influence on organizational theory was evident from the beginning – “indeed, in many ways it was the beginning!” (Scott, 2003, p. 166).

  2. 2.

    For a highly instructive critique of this interpretation, see Tyrell (1981, p. 46f.).

  3. 3.

    The extent to which Weber’s material analyses already anticipate Luhmann’s insights into organizational sociology with regard to informal structures – without, of course, achieving (or even striving for) a comparable degree of generalization and theoretical systematization – can be seen, for example, in his debate speech at the Vienna conference of the Verein für Sozialpolitik in 1909, which he concludes with the remark that a “business officialdom stripped of its divine nimbus” and susceptible to corruption, such as he thinks he can identify in the USA, England or France, is under certain circumstances more “efficient” than the “highly moral, authoritarian transfigured German officialdom” (Weber, 1988b, p. 416). The echoes of Luhmann’s notion of “usable illegality” are hard to ignore. Weber’s purely power-political value considerations, towards which “illegality” is supposed to be more efficient than rigid conformity, are admittedly different from those of Luhmann, who relates the concept to the problems of adaptation and self-preservation of organizations in general. Structurally, however, they are descriptions of the same phenomenon.

  4. 4.

    Of course, such a critique must not forget that the formal type of bureaucracy alone was not sufficient for Weber to justify the “superiority” of occidental forms of organization, but that he sought above all to emphasize the extra-organizational, especially religious, preconditions of civil service discipline, which remains a central component of the efficiency of bureaucracies.

  5. 5.

    For a recent, quite elegant attempt to interpret Weber’s work from such critical-normative positions, see Marty (2020, p. 22ff.).

  6. 6.

    The closedness as a social system is already contained in Weber’s concept of the “organisation” (Verband). Only the autonomy and autonomous capacity to act seems to contradict Weber’s concept of bureaucracy, since at the head of his bureaucracies there is typically no rationally trained bureaucrat, but a hereditary or official charismatic ruler standing outside the bureaucratic order (cf. Weber, 2019, p. 401). However, the dependence of bureaucratic rule on specialist and official knowledge in particular often causes a tendency for the bureaucratic apparatus to become independent of its master, whereby it itself gains autonomy and, so to speak, collective “agency” (cf. Breuer, 1997, p. 121f.).

  7. 7.

    At this point, Weber also uses the word “Organisation” in German, whereas instead, where the English translation speaks otherwise of organizations, he usually uses the word “Verband”.

  8. 8.

    Another reason is probably that America’s modern large corporations were already described in terms of state bureaucracies and structured according to them during their rise towards the end of the nineteenth century (cf. Graeber, 2015, p. 11f.). The concept of a “bureaucratic administrative staff” therefore also seemed appropriate for private capitalist organizations.

  9. 9.

    That Parsons was well aware of the difficulties of translating economy and society is shown by the countless footnotes he added to his attempt to translate the first three chapters. And it is also undeniable what Lawrence A. Scaff remarks about this very translation: “pried loose from their linguistic matrix, some concepts lose too much of their original connotation”. Whether Parsons’ translation can therefore already be considered “as close as we can come to Weber’s last words in social theory”, however, remains more than questionable (cf. Scaff, 2011, p. 237).

  10. 10.

    The same is the case for Keith Tribe’s translation, which as the most up-to-date translation is nevertheless used here.

  11. 11.

    For more recent findings on contractual wage labor in the first known great empire of Assyria, see also Radner (2015, p. 333ff.).

References

  • Blau, P. M. (1952). The dynamics of bureaucratic structure. A study of interpersonal relations in two government agencies. Columbia University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Breuer, S. (1997). Rationale Herrschaft. Zu einer Kategorie Max Webers. In W. Seibel, M. Medick-Krakau, H. Münkler, & MTh. Greven (Hrsg.), Demokratische Politik (S. 106–134). Westdeutscher Verlag.

    Google Scholar 

  • Breuer, S. (2011). „Herrschaft“ in der Soziologie Max Webers. Harrassowitz.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bruch, M. (2000). Herrschaft in der modernen Gesellschaft. Zur Bedeutung des Organisationsverhältnisses in kritischen Theorien der Gesellschaft. Westdeutscher Verlag.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Cohen, J., Hazelrigg, L. E., & Pope, W. (1975). De-parsonizing Weber: A critique of Parsons’ interpretation of Weber’s sociology. American Sociological Review, 40, 229–241.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gabriel, K. (1979). Analysen der Organisationsgesellschaft. Ein kritischer Vergleich der Gesellschaftstheorien Max Webers, Niklas Luhmanns und der phänomenologischen Soziologie. Campus.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gouldner, A. W. (1954). Patterns of industrial bureaucracy. A case study of modern factory administration. The Free Press of Glencoe.

    Google Scholar 

  • Graeber, D. (2015). The utopia of rules. On technology, stupidity, and the secret joys of bureaucracy. Melville House.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hennis, W. (1987). Max Webers Fragestellung. Studien zur Biographie des Werks. Mohr.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hermes, S. (2004). Vom politischen Traditionalismus zum ökonomischen Rationalismus. Kapitalistische Wirtschaft und patrimoniale Herrschaft bei Max Weber. Archiv Für Kulturgeschichte, 86, 179–212.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaube, J. (2014). Max Weber. Ein Leben zwischen den Epochen (3rd ed.). Rowohlt.

    Google Scholar 

  • Luhmann, N. (2018b). Zweck – Herrschaft – System: Grundbegriffe und Prämissen Max Webers (1964). In E. Lukas & V. Tacke (Hrsg.), Schriften zur Organisation 1. Die Wirklichkeit der Organisation (Bd. 1, LSO, S. 153–184). Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marty, C. (2020). Max Weber. Ein Denker der Freiheit (2nd ed.). Beltz.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mayntz, R. (1968). Max Webers Idealtypus der Bürokratie und die Organisationssoziologie. In R. Mayntz (Hrsg.), Bürokratische Organisation (S. 27–35). Kiepenheuer & Witsch.

    Google Scholar 

  • Merton, R. K. (1940). Bureaucratic structure and personality. Social Forces, 18, 560–568.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Parsons, T. (Hrsg.). (1947). Max Weber: The theory of social and economic organization. Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Parsons, T. (1960). Max Weber. American Sociological Review, 25, 750–752.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Radner, K. (2015). Hired labor in the neo-Assyrian empire. In P. Steinkeller & M. Hudson (Hrsg.), Labor in the ancient world. A colloquium held at Hirschbach (Saxony), April 2005 (S. 329–343). ISLET.

    Google Scholar 

  • Roethlisberger, F. J., & Dickson, W. J. (1949). Management and the worker. A account of a research program conducted by the western electric company, Hawthorne Works, Chicago (9th ed.). Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scaff, L. A. (2011). Max Weber in America. Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Schluchter, W. (1979). Die Entwicklung des okzidentalen Rationalismus. Eine Analyse von Max Webers Gesellschaftsgeschichte. Mohr Siebeck.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schluchter, W. (1985). Aspekte bürokratischer Herrschaft. Studien zur Interpretation der fortschreitenden Industriegesellschaft. Suhrkamp.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schluchter, W. (2009). Der Kapitalismus als eine universalgeschichtliche Erscheinung. Max Webers institutionenbezogene Analyse. In M. Stachura, A. Bienfait, G. Albert, & S. Sigmund (Hrsg.), Der Sinn der Institutionen. Mehr-Ebenen- und Mehr-Seiten-Analyse (S. 209–235). VS Verlag.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scott, W. R. (2003). Organizations. Rational, natural, and open systems (5th ed.). Pearson Education.

    Google Scholar 

  • Selznick, P. (1943). An approach to a theory of bureaucracy. American Sociological Review, 8, 47–54.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Swedberg, R. (2003). Principles of economic sociology. Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Tribe, K. (2007). Talcott Parsons as translator of Max Weber’s basic sociological categories. History of European Ideas, 33, 212–233.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tyrell, H. (1981). Ist der Webersche Bürokratietypus ein objektiver Richtigkeitstypus? Anmerkungen zu einer These von Renate Mayntz. Zeitschrift für Soziologie, 10, 38–49.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weber, M. (1950). General economic history (2nd ed.). The Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weber, M. (1978). Economy and society. An outline of interpretive sociology. University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weber, M. (1988a). Gesammelte Aufsätze zur Religionssoziologie. Band 1 (9th ed.). Mohr.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weber, M. (1988b). Gesammelte Aufsätze zur Soziologie und Sozialpolitik (2nd ed.). Mohr.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weber, M. (1998). The agrarian sociology of ancient civilizations. Verso.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weber, M. (2009). Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft. Herrschaft. Mohr.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weber, M. (2019). Economy and society. A new translation. Harvard University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2022 The Author(s), under exclusive license to Springer Fachmedien Wiesbaden GmbH, part of Springer Nature

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Jakobs, P. (2022). Max Weber and the Sociology of Organization. In: Max Weber and the sociology of organization. Springer, Wiesbaden. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-658-40287-7_2

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-658-40287-7_2

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Wiesbaden

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-658-40286-0

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-658-40287-7

  • eBook Packages: Social SciencesSocial Sciences (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics