Skip to main content

Repeated Response versus Strategy Method. Experimental Evidence from an Oversight Game

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Jahrbuch für Handlungs- und Entscheidungstheorie

Abstract

Existing laboratory research suggests that the Nash equilibrium in mixed strategies has limited capacity to predict subjects’ behavior in an Oversight Game (OG). We propose that this inconsistency between the game-theoretical solution and subjects’ actual behavior may be due to the elicitation method used in previous laboratory experiments. To test this conjecture, we design a laboratory experiment in which subjects play the OG either using the conventional repeated response method, in which subjects are informed of their opponent’s action after each period, or using a novel strategy method, in which subjects choose their mixed strategy and let the computer randomize. Comparing the elicitation methods shows that it has no effect on subjects’ decisions in the OG, regardless of whether the repeated response or strategy method has been implemented. Under both conditions, subjects uniformly deviate from the Nash equilibrium in mixed strategy.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 49.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 64.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    In addition, subjects cognitive and strategic capability matters, especially with backwards induction, but also with the comprehension of best strategies in general (Rauhut, 2009; Grehl and Tutić, 2015). For example, Palacios-Huerta und Volij (2008) compare randomization abilities of professional football players and student subjects and find that only players with intensive amounts of experience are able to come close to mixed strategy equilibrium. Walker und Wooders (2001) find similar result among professional contestants in the Wimbledon tennis tournament.

  2. 2.

    Instructions, data and syntax are available from the corresponding author upon request. See [https://uol.de/f/1/inst/sowi/ag/polsys/ONLINE_APPENDIX_Repeated_Response.pdf] for the online Appendix.

  3. 3.

    Due to a programming error, we had to remove 130 cases from the repeated response design for scenario 4.

References

  • Anderhub, Vital, Dirk Engelmann, and Werner Güth (2002), “An experimental study of the repeated trust game with incomplete information.” Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 48, 197–216.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Avenhaus, R. (2004), “Applications of inspection games.” Mathematical Modelling and Analysis, 9, 179–192.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Azar, Ofer and Michael Bar-Eli (2011), “Do soccer players play the mixed-strategy Nash equilibrium?” Applied Economics 43, 2591–3601.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bock, Olaf, Ingmar Baetge, and Andreas Nicklisch (2014), “hroot – hamburg registration and organization online tool.” European Economic Review, 71, 117–120.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brandts, Jordi and Garry Charness (2011), “The strategy versus the direct- response method: a first survey of experimental comparisons.” Experimental Economics, 14, 375–398.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Casari, Marco and Timothy N. Cason (2009), “The strategy method lowers measured trustworthy behavior.” Economics Letters 103, 157–159.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chiappori, Pierre Andre, Steven Levitt and Timothy Groseclose (2002), “Testing mixed-strategy equilibria when players are heterogeneous: The case of penalty kicks in soccer.” American Economic Review 92, 1138–1151.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fischbacher, Urs (2007), “z-tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments.” Experimental Economics, 10, 171–178.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Giegerenzer, Gerd and D. Goldstein (1996), “Reasoning the fast and frugal way: Models of bounded rationality.” Psychological Review, 103, 650–669.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goeree, Jacob K. and Charles A. Holt (2001), “Ten little treasures of game theory and ten intuitive contradictions.” The American Economic Review, 91, 1402–1422.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grehl, Sascha and Andreas Tutić (2015), “Experimental evidence on iterated reasoning in games.” PLOS ONE, 10, e0136524. https://doi.org/https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0136524

  • Greiner, Ben (2015), “Subject pool recruitment procedures: Organizing experiments with Orsee.” Journal of the Economic Science Association, 1, 114–125.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McCarty, Nolan and Adam Meirowitz (2007), Political Game Theory: An Introduction. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Minozzi, William and Jonathan Woon (2020), “Direct response and the strategy method in an experimental cheap talk game.” Journal of Behavioral and Experimental Economics 85, 101498.

    Google Scholar 

  • Molnar, Andras (2019), “SMARTRIQS: A Simple Method Allowing Real-Time Respondent Interaction in Qualtrics Surveys.” Journal of Behavioral and Experimental Finance, 22, 161–169.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nash, John (1951), “Non-cooperative games.” The Annals of Mathematics, 54, 286–295.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nosenzo, Daniele, Theo Offerman, Martin Sefton and Ailko van der Veen (2014), “Encouraging compliance: Bonuses versus fines in inspection games.” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 30, 623–648.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ochs, Jack (1995), “Games with unique, mixed strategy equilibria: An experimental study.” Games and Economic Behavior, 10, 202–217.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Palacios-Huerta, Ignacio (2003), “Professionals play minimax.” Review of Economic Studies 70, 395–415

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Palacios-Huerta, Ignacio and Oscar Volij (2008), “Experimentia docet: Professionals play minimax in laboratory experiments.” Econometrica, 76, 71–115.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Palan, Stefan and Christian Schitter (2018). “Prolific.ac – A subject pool for online experiments.” Journal of Behavioral and Experimental Finance 17, 22–27.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rauhut, H. (2009), “Higher punishment, less control? Experimental evidence on the inspection game.” Rationality and Society, 21, 359–392.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rauhut, H. (2015), “Stronger inspection incentives, less crime? Further experimental evidence on inspection games.” Rationality and Society, 27, 414–454.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rauhut, Heiko and Fabian Winter (2010), “A sociological perspective on measuring social norms by means of strategy method experiment.” Social Science Research, 39, 1181–1194.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Selten, R. (1967), “Die Strategiemethode zur Erforschung des eingeschränkt rationalen Verhaltens im Rahmen eines Oligopolexperiments.” In Beiträge zur experimentellen Wirtschaftsforschung (H. Sauermann, ed.), 136–168, Mohr, Tübingen.

    Google Scholar 

  • Walker, Mark and John Wooders (2001), “Minimax play at Wimbledon.” American Economic Review, 95, 1521–1538.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Maximilian Lutz .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2022 Springer Fachmedien Wiesbaden GmbH, ein Teil von Springer Nature

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Lutz, M., Shikano, S., Tepe, M. (2022). Repeated Response versus Strategy Method. Experimental Evidence from an Oversight Game. In: Sauermann, J., Tepe, M., Debus, M. (eds) Jahrbuch für Handlungs- und Entscheidungstheorie. Jahrbuch für Handlungs- und Entscheidungstheorie. Springer VS, Wiesbaden. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-658-35878-5_7

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-658-35878-5_7

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer VS, Wiesbaden

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-658-35877-8

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-658-35878-5

  • eBook Packages: Social Science and Law (German Language)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics