Skip to main content

German Unification and the Effects on Central and Eastern Europe

  • Conference paper
Economic Transformation in Eastern Europe and East Asia
  • 40 Accesses

Abstract

It all started when Hungary began in May 1989 to clear away the barbed wire marking its border with Austria and then in September to allow refugees from the GDR to continue on to West Germany. A mere two months later the Berlin Wall had crumbled, for nearly thirty years a grim symbol of the East-West conflict in Europe. Less than a year later the unification of the two German states was reality. In the very next year Croatia and Slovenia declared their independence from Yugoslavia. And finally, at the end of 1991, the Soviet Union collapsed, not only marking its end in post-war history as a super-power, but also the end of its entire course of its history since its founding in 1922. In a postscript to this development, the Czech and Slovak Republics decided to end their union in 1993. In a few breath-taking years the political order in Central and Eastern Europe had been turned upside down.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Note

  1. Wemer Abelshauser, Wirtschafisgeschichte der Bundesrepublik Deutschland 1945–1980, Frankfurt a.M. 1983, pp. 40–45.

    Google Scholar 

  2. Rainer Klumpf, Wirtschafisgeschichte der Bundesrepublik Deutschland, Stuttgart 1985, pp. 104–105.

    Google Scholar 

  3. W. W. Rostow, The World Economy, London 1978, p. 408; Knut Borchardt, “Die Bundesrepublik Deutschland in den säkularen Trends der wirtschaftlichen Entwicklung,” in Wachstum, Krisen, Handlungsspielräume der Wirtschaftspolitik, ed. Knut Borchardt, Gottingen 1982, p. 144; W. Abelshauser, Die langen Fünfiiger Jahre, Dusseldorf 1987, pp. 56-60.

    Google Scholar 

  4. Hans C. Graf von Seherr-Thoss, Die deutsche Automobilindustrie, Stuttgart 1987, 2nd ed., pp. 316, 417.

    Google Scholar 

  5. An exhaustive examination of the term “consumer revolution” in post-war Japan is to be found in Kazushi Ohkawa & Henry Rosovsky, Japanese Economic Growth, Stanford 1973, pp. 157–160. However, the authors overlook the fact that the concept traditional cannot be definitively defined in modern Japan. For an interpretation of the change in life style in Japan in the age of mass consumption cf. Kounosuke Qdaka, “Seichou no Kiseki” [Trace of Growth](2), in Koudoseichou[High Economic Growth], ed. Yasukichi Yasuba—Takenori Inoki, Tokyo 1989, pp. 181-200; Takafusa Nakamura, Shouwashi[History of Shouwa] II, Tokyo 1993, pp. 554-560; Daikichi Irokawa, Shouwashi Sesouhen[History of Shouwa Social Life], Tokyo 1994, pp. 47-55, 101-103.

    Google Scholar 

  6. Masayasu Miyazaki & Osamu Itou, “Senji-Sengo no Sangyou to Kigyou [Industries and Enterprises in the Wartime and after the War],” in Keikakuka to Minshuka[Plannization (sic) and Democratization], ed. T. Nakamura, Tokyo 1989, p. 180.

    Google Scholar 

  7. Osamu Soda, Rome wo Kangaeru [Think about Rice], Tokyo 1989, p. 125.

    Google Scholar 

  8. Shortly before the outbreak of the first oil crisis, “Ohkawa and Rosovsky argued that, [a]fter World War H, Japan’s foreign trade proportions declined markedly especially compared to 1910–1940. Although the reasons for this are hard to pinpoint, there is no doubt that this decline must have contributed to an easier situation with respect to any external constraint.” Ohkawa—Rosovsky, op. dr., p. 188.

    Google Scholar 

  9. Statistisches Bundesamt, Statistisches Jahrbuch für die Bundesrepublik Deutschland 1954, pp. 279, 148.

    Google Scholar 

  10. OECD, Historical Statistics 1960–1990, Paris 1992, p. 71.

    Google Scholar 

  11. Ippei Yamazawa Yuzou Yamamoto, Chouki Keizai Toukei Suikei to Bunseki. 14: Boueki to Kokusai Syuhshi[Estimates of Long-term Economic Statistics of Japan since 1868. 14: Foreign Trade and Balance of Payments], Tokyo 1979, p. 3; Ohkurashou [Ministry of Finance], Zaisei Kinyuh Toükei Geppou[Monthly Report of Financial and Monetary Statistics], Kaku Kokusai Shuhshi Tokushuh[Each Special Issue for Balance of Payments].

    Google Scholar 

  12. Historical Statistics, p. 71.

    Google Scholar 

  13. Japan’s supposed’ export-led growth’ has already been examined by Ohkawa and Rosovsky. “Our position is that Japan’s rate of growth of exports has been high and well above world averages because the rate of growth of its economy and especially of its industry has been high and well above world averages, and not vice versa. Given the complex interaction between domestic growth and international trade, it is not easy to demonstrate the validity of this view conclusively, but our thinking runs along these general lines.” Ohkawa & Rosovsky, op. cit., p. 173.

    Google Scholar 

  14. Historical Statistics, p.62.

    Google Scholar 

  15. ibid, p.40.

    Google Scholar 

  16. Hartmut Kaelble, Auf dem Weg zu einer europäischen Gesellschaft, Munich 1987, pp. 25–30, argues for a European industial intensive employment structure. He views this European particularity as being closely related to the strong export orientation of European industry and the strong position of the craft trades. But his thesis still lacks confirmation, since the sectoral distribution of employment and added value are not always congruent, to say nothing about discrepancies in the industrial classifications in various countries. For example, in those handicraft branches where production and small-scale trade are combined in the same firm, they are conventially listed in Japanese statistics in the tertiary sector. As a consequence, the secondary sector in Japan is statistically weaker than it really is. Cf. Soumuchou Toukeikyoku [Management and Coordination Agency, Statistics Bureau], Nihon Hyoujun Sangyau Bunrui[Standard Industrial Classification of Japan], 1993, pp. 442, 470-492.

    Google Scholar 

  17. Statistisches, Jahrbuch 1993 für die BRD, p. 323.

    Google Scholar 

  18. Statistisches Amt des Vereinigten Wirtschaftsgebietes, Wirtschaft und Statistik, Vol. 1, New Series, No. 11, Feb. 1950, p. 341.

    Google Scholar 

  19. Soumuchou Toukeikyoku, Nihon Toukei Nenkan[Japan Statistical Yearbook], 1993/94, pp. 410–411.

    Google Scholar 

  20. ibid.

    Google Scholar 

  21. In 1965 Japan achieved for the first time since the Second World War an export surplus in trade with the USA. Since then its trade balance with the USA has always been positive, excepting only 1967 and 1975. Zaisei Kinyuh Geppou, No. 496, 1993.8, pp. 66–67.

    Google Scholar 

  22. Cf. Carsten Lüders, “Die Regelung der Ruhrfrage in den Verhandlungen über die politische und ökonomische Stabilisierung Westdeutschlands 1947–1949,” in Wirtschaftspolitik im britischen Besatzungsgebiet 1945–1949, ed. Dietmar Petzina & Walter Euchner, Düsseldorf 1984.

    Google Scholar 

  23. For early arguments on the divergence in market orientations between East and West Germany cf. Max Weber, “Die wirtschaftlichen Grundlagen des ‘Imperialismus’”, in Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft, ed. Max Weber, Tübingen 1922. After the Second World War these problems were taken up again in the seminal work of Knut Borchardt. Cf. his “Regionale Wachstumsdifferenzierung in Deutschland im 19. Jahrhundert unter besonderer Berücksichtigung des Ost-West-Gefalles”, in Wirtschaft, Geschichte und Wirtschaftsgeschichte, ed. Wilhelm Abel, Knut Borchardt, et. al., Stuttgart 1966. In Japan Tomoo Matsuda has studied the East-West differentiation in Germany since the 1940s. Cf. Tomoo Matsuda, Kindai no Shiteki-Kouzouron[Historical Structure of Modern Times], Tokyo 1948.

    Google Scholar 

  24. On the crisis of the north cf. Rheinisch-Westfälisches Institut für Wirtschaftsforschung (RWI), Nordrhein-Westfalen in der Krise—Krise in Nordrhein-Westfalen? Berlin 1985.

    Google Scholar 

  25. For an economic-historical analysis of the “south-north-gap” cf. Hubert Kiesewetter, “Das wirtschaftliche Gefalle zwischen Nord-und Süddeutschland in historischer Perspektive,” in Neues Archivför Niedersachsen, vol. 35, no. 4, 1986. He regards the five northern Länder as comprising the “North.” The term was examined in a regional-sociological view by Jürgen Friedrichs, Hartmut Häussennann—Walter Siebel, eds., Süd-Nord-Gefälle in der Bundesrepublik? Opladen 1986.

    Google Scholar 

  26. Just the same, the proportion of the population living in North-Rhine-Westphalia rose slightly from 26.5% (1950) to 27.2% (1990). But in the same period the proportion living in Baden-Württemberg rose more rapidly, from 12.9% to 15.4%. Statistisches Jahrbuch för die BRD.1952, 1992.

    Google Scholar 

  27. On the profound convergence of the German and French societies after World War II cf. Hartmut Kaelble, Nachbarn am Rhein, Munich 1991.

    Google Scholar 

  28. Historical Statistics, pp. 40, 62.

    Google Scholar 

  29. ibid., pp. 62-63.

    Google Scholar 

  30. Cf. Kaelble, Nachbarn, chap. 7.

    Google Scholar 

  31. Historical Statistics, p. 66.

    Google Scholar 

  32. ibid., p. 71.

    Google Scholar 

  33. For a detailed account of the rapid and vigorous convergence in consumption styles cf. Kaelble, Nachbarn, pp. 164–166.

    Google Scholar 

  34. OECD, National Accounts. Main Aggregates, Vol. 1, 1960–1992, Paris 1994, pp. 146–147.

    Google Scholar 

  35. On the growing similarities of the European societies in the 20th century cf. Kaelble, Auf dem Weg.

    Google Scholar 

  36. Statistisches Bundesamt, Lange Reihen, pp. 156–157; Statistisches Jahrbuch für die BRD, all vols.

    Google Scholar 

  37. Werner Glastetter, Günter Högemann—Ralf Marquardt, Die wirtschaftliche Entwicklung in der Bundesrepublik Deutschland, 1950–1989, Frankfurt 1991, p. 167.

    Google Scholar 

  38. Historical Statistics, p. 48. For a critical examination of evaluations of the up-turn since 1982 cf. Glastetter, et. al., op.cit., pp. 37-46.

    Google Scholar 

  39. Paolo Cecchini, The European Challenge 1992, N.P. 1988.

    Google Scholar 

  40. Art. 1 states: “The aim of this Agreement of association is to promote a continuous and balanced strengthening of trade and economic relations between the Contracting Parties … with a view to creating a homogeneous European Economic Area.” Council of the EC / Commission of the EC, Agreement on the European Economic Area, Luxembourg 1992.

    Google Scholar 

  41. Willy Kraus, Soziale Marktwirtschaft, Bonn 1990, p. 24.

    Google Scholar 

  42. Glastötter et al., op. cit., p. 40.

    Google Scholar 

  43. On the transformation from centrally planned to social market economies in the GDR and East and South-East Europe see Kraus, op. cit.

    Google Scholar 

  44. On the rapid changes in the estimations of the total value of GDR assets through the federal government cf. Eckart Schremmer, “Integration und Desintegration: Die Vereinigung der beiden Teile Deutschlands, DDR und BRD 1989 bis 1993. Vortrag in 1993. 11.,” in Doitzukeizai no Rekishiteki-Kuhkan[Historical Spaces of German Economy], ed. Minora Morota et al., Kyoto 1994, pp. 277–278.

    Google Scholar 

  45. This scenario has by now been realized, though only fragmentarily, since the East Germans—with their high purchasing power potential—bought heavily on the West German and international import markets. The hope of a reconstruction of the industrial sites between Elbe and Oder was disappointed, since the unexpected deindustrialization in East Germany continued on until 1993. Ibid., pp. 284 ff.

    Google Scholar 

  46. Translator’s note: The “minor-German” unification was historically the unification of the German states in 1871 to form the German Empire, excluding Austria. The groβdeutsche or “major-German” unification would have included Austria.

    Google Scholar 

  47. For a diagnosis and therapy from the hands of practitioners cf. Das Süd-Nord-Gefalle, ed. Rüdiger von Voss — Karl Friedrich, Stuttgart 1986.

    Google Scholar 

  48. The percentage of the GDR population living in the southern 8 districts declined from 66.6% in 1946 to 63.2% in 1988. Statistisches Jahrbuch der Deutschen Demokratischen Republik, annually. This might be regarded as one of the few plausible data in the economic statistics.

    Google Scholar 

  49. ibid.

    Google Scholar 

  50. What stands out is a history of Saxony, which appeared shortly before the GDR’s downfall, concluding that present-day Saxony had a highly balanced economy and not mentioning relations to the Berlin region at all. Cf. Geschichte Sachsens, ed. Karl Czok, Weimar 1989, pp. 586 ff.

    Google Scholar 

  51. For an analysis of the voting results cf. Wolfgang-Uwe friedlich, Pluralismus in der DDR, Königswinter 1990, pp. 43–

    Google Scholar 

  52. Unemployment in Hamburg in 1990 was at 10.5% the second highest of all the eleven old states after Bremen. In the meantime, it has managed to reduce this considerably. Consequently, in 1992 Hamburg was with 7.9% unemployment in the middle of the scale. In this far, Hamburg was able to profit the most by reunification, especially through a rapid reconstruction of the connection with Berlin. Statistisches Jahrbuch 1993 für die BRD, p. 128.

    Google Scholar 

  53. Rhein-Main-Donau AG, RMD INTERN 3/1992, Eröffnung des Main-Donau-Kanals.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 1996 Springer-Verlag Berlin • Heidelberg

About this paper

Cite this paper

Watanabe, H. (1996). German Unification and the Effects on Central and Eastern Europe. In: Hax, H., Klenner, W., Kraus, W., Matsuda, T., Nakamura, T. (eds) Economic Transformation in Eastern Europe and East Asia. Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-85229-9_9

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-85229-9_9

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-642-85231-2

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-642-85229-9

  • eBook Packages: Springer Book Archive

Publish with us

Policies and ethics