Advertisement

Social capital and cooperation: Communication, bounded rationality, and behavioral heuristics

  • Roy Gardner
  • Elinor Ostrom
  • James Walker
Conference paper

Abstract

Common-pool resources are natural or man made resources used in common by multiple users, where yield is subtractable (rival) and exclusion is nontrivial (but not necessarily impossible). The role of face-to-face communication in CPR situations, where individuals must repeatedly decide on the number of resource units to withdraw from a common-pool, is open to considerable theoretical and policy debate. In this paper, we summarize the findings from a series of experiments in which we operationalize face-to-face communication (without the presence of external enforcement). In an attempt to understand the high degree of cooperation observed in the laboratory, we turn to a bounded rationality explanation as a starting point for understanding how cooperative behavior can be supported in decision environments where game theory suggests it will not.

Keywords

Social Capital Nash Equilibrium Measured Reaction Large Reaction Group Investment 
These keywords were added by machine and not by the authors. This process is experimental and the keywords may be updated as the learning algorithm improves.

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  1. Banks, J.S., & Calvert, R.L. (1992a). A battle-of-the-sexes game with incomplete information. Games and Economic Behavior, 4, 1–26.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Banks, J.S., & Calvert, R.L. (1992b). Communication and efficiency in coordination games. Working Paper. Rochester, N.Y.: University of Rochester, Department of Economics and Department of Political Science.Google Scholar
  3. Benoit, J., & Krishna, V. (1985). Finitely repeated games. Econometrìca, 53, 905–922.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Caldwell, M.D. (1976). Communication and sex effects in a five-person prisoners’ dilemma game. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 33(3), 273–280.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Dawes, R.M., McTavish, J., & Shaklee, H. (1977). Behavior, communication, and assumptions about other people’s behavior in a commons dilemma situation. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 35(1), 1–11.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Edney, J.J., & Harper, C.S. (1978). The commons dilemma: A review of contributions from psychology. Environmental Management, 2(6), 491–507.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. El-Gamal, M., McKelvey, R.D., & Palfrey, T.R. (1991). A Bayesian sequential experimental study of learning in games. Social Science Working Paper no. 757. Pasadena: California Institute of Technology.Google Scholar
  8. Friedman, J.W. (1990). Game theory with applications to economics (2nd ed.). New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  9. Groner, R., Groner, M., Bischof, W.F. (1983). Methods of heuristics. Hillsdale, N.J.: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates.Google Scholar
  10. Hackett, S., Schlager, E., & Walker, J.M. (1992). The role of communication in resolving commons dilemmas: Experimental evidence with heterogeneous appropriators. Working Paper. Bloomington: Indiana University, Workshop in Political Theory and Policy Analysis.Google Scholar
  11. Isaac, R.M., & Walker, J.M. (1988a). Communication and free-riding behavior: The voluntary contribution mechanism. Economic Inquiry, 24(4), 585–608.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. Isaac, R.M., & Walker, J.M. (1988b). Group size effects in public goods provision: The voluntary contributions mechanism. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 103, 179–199.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Isaac, R.M., & Walker, J.M. (1991). Costly communication: An experiment in a nested public goods problem. In T.R. Palfrey (Ed.), Laboratory research in political economy (pp. 269–286). Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
  14. Jerdee, T.H., & Rosen, B. (1974). Effects of opportunity to communicate and visibility of individual decisions on behavior in the common interest. Journal of Applied Psychology, 59(6), 712–716.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. Keohane, R.O. (1986). Reciprocity in international relations. International Organization, 40, 1–27.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. Krueger, A.O. (1974). The political economy of the rent-seeking society. American Economic Review, 64, 291–303.Google Scholar
  17. Mitzkewitz, M., & Nagel, R. (1991). Envy, greed, and anticipation in ultimatum games with incomplete information: An experimental study. Discussion Paper B-181. Bonn: University of Bonn, Sonderforschungsbereich 303.)Google Scholar
  18. Orbell, J.M., van de Kragt, & Dawes, R.M. (1991). Covenants without the sword: The role of promises in social dilemma circumstances. In K.J. Kofford & J.B. Miller (Eds.), Social norms and economic institutions (pp. 117–134). Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
  19. Ostrom, E., & Walker, J.M. (1991). Communication in a commons: Cooperation without external enforcement. In T.R. Palfrey (Ed.), Laboratory research in political economy (pp. 287–322). Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
  20. Ostrom, E., Walker, J., & Gardner, R. (1992). Covenants with and without a sword: Selfgovernance is possible. American Political Science Review, 86(2), 404–417.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. Rockenbach, B., & Uhlich, G.R. (1989). The negotiation agreement area: An experimental analysis of two-person characteristic function games. Discussion Paper B-126. Bonn: University of Bonn, Sonderforschungsbereich 303.Google Scholar
  22. Runge, C.F. (1984). Institutions and the free rider: The assurance problem in collective action. Journal of Politics, 46(1), 154–181.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. Schotter, A. (1980). The economic theory of social institutions. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  24. Selten, R. (1975). Reexamination of the perfectness concept for equilibrium points in extensive games. International Journal of Game Theory, 4, 25–55.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  25. Selten, R., Mitzkewitz, M., & Uhlich, G.R. (1988). Duopoly strategies programmed by experienced players. Discussion Paper B-172. Bonn: University of Bonn Special Research Project 303.Google Scholar
  26. Tullock, G. (1967). The welfare costs of tariff monopolies and theft. Western Economic Journal, 5, 224–232.Google Scholar
  27. van de Kragt, A., Dawes, R.M., Orbell, J.M., Braver, S.R., & Wilson, L.A. (1986). Doing well and doing good as ways of resolving social dilemmas. In H. Wilke, D. Messick, & C. Rutte (Eds.), Experimental social dilemmas (pp. 177–204). Frankfurt am Main, FRG: Verlag Peter Lang.Google Scholar
  28. Walker, J.M., Gardner, R., & Ostrom, E. (1991). Rent dissipation and balanced deviation disequilibrium in common pool resources: Experimental evidence. In R. Selten (Ed.), Game equilibrium models II: Methods, morals, and markets (pp. 337–367). Berlin: Springer-Verlag.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer-Verlag Berlin · Heidelberg 1984

Authors and Affiliations

  • Roy Gardner
  • Elinor Ostrom
  • James Walker
    • 1
  1. 1.Department of EconomicsIndiana UniversityBloomingtonUSA

Personalised recommendations