Skip to main content

Part of the book series: Lecture Notes in Economics and Mathematical Systems ((LNE,volume 476))

  • 138 Accesses

Abstract

The main purpose of this chapter is to build and explore a benchmark macro-model in a deterministic setting of financial markets. Although this model exhibits highly unrealistic features like a constant short-term interest rate and thus a flat term structure of interest rates, it has nevertheless some merits: first of all, the income and debt dynamics are linear so that we can calculate and analyze the time paths of these variables explicitly. This delivers clear-cut results with regard to economic growth and public indebtedness. Second, the stochastic macro-model to be developed later on converges to this deterministic version when risk disappears. We can check the correctness of the reduced-form dynamics of our stochastic model by simply looking at the deterministic model. Third, by comparing the outcomes of the stochastic version with the deterministic one, we can discern the qualitative effects brought about by the introduction of risk.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 39.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Notes

  1. Barro/Sala-i-Martin (1995, Chapter 1.3 and 4.1) call this production function ‘A-K technology’. They also show that this type of production function is the simplest one that generates endogenous growth.

    Google Scholar 

  2. We have omitted the time index and will continue to do so mainly for notational convenience. The reader should note that all variables in this chapter are described by capital letters and are functions of time.

    Google Scholar 

  3. From now on dots on variables denote derivatives with regard to time.

    Google Scholar 

  4. Government debt in form of short-term bonds can hence be thought to be rolled over continuously. We abstract from the issue of government default because every specification of a possible default of the government would be arbitrary and thus ad-hoc if we did not model government behavior endogenously.

    Google Scholar 

  5. Note from (2.3a) that any pair of stocks of the three assets could be thought to be control variables since by choosing two stocks the third stock is determined via (2.3a) given the stock of wealth.

    Google Scholar 

  6. The original reference is Pontryagin et al. (1962). Books including economic examples of how to use this Maximum Principle are Kamien/Schwartz (1991), Chiang (1992), Léonard/Van Long (1992) and Takayama (1993).

    Google Scholar 

  7. We do not consider the second-order condition here since it is extremely easy to see that it holds as long as γ is positive.

    Google Scholar 

  8. Of course, one could ask why we did not include capital accumulation as another dynamic constraint into the decision problem of the representative household since this would probably have led to a consumption/saving behavior of the private sector that does not include the danger of zero capital stocks. The reason is simple: it seems unreasonable that private households take into consideration the aggregate capital accumulation of the economy. If they did, the assumption of price taking behavior would become logically unsustainable.

    Google Scholar 

  9. Simultaneously, we can also see that it is sufficient in order to get always positive growth rates when τ ≤ αк-δ-p holds.

    Google Scholar 

  10. This means that „…a poor economy tends to grow faster than a rich one, so that the poor country tends to catch up with the rich one…“ (Barro/Sala-i-Martin (1995, p. 383)).

    Google Scholar 

  11. As Obstfeld/Rogoff (1996, Supplements to Chapter 2) argue for the case of infinite-horizon representative agent models, the government’s intertemporal solvency or no Ponzi-game constraint is always fulfilled when the transversality condition holds.

    Google Scholar 

  12. We are well aware of the fact that this interpretation has a kind of Malthusian-flavored character which many economists do not like and share.

    Google Scholar 

  13. For a general exposition of how to solve systems of first-order differential equations, see Boyce/DiPrima (1997, Chapter 7).

    Google Scholar 

  14. Compare Boyce/DiPrima (1997, Chapter 7.7).

    Google Scholar 

  15. We decided to put the first eigenvalue into the fundamental solution instead of the second. The other way round is, of course, also possible since we consider the case were both eigenvalues are identical.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 1999 Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Demmel, R. (1999). The basic deterministic macroeconomic model. In: Fiscal Policy, Public Debt and the Term Structure of Interest Rates. Lecture Notes in Economics and Mathematical Systems, vol 476. Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-58595-1_2

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-58595-1_2

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-540-66243-3

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-642-58595-1

  • eBook Packages: Springer Book Archive

Publish with us

Policies and ethics