Skip to main content

Conscription and the allocation of production factors

  • Chapter
  • 166 Accesses

Part of the book series: Contributions to Economics ((CE))

Abstract

As demonstrated in chapter 2, the use of production means in the armed forces, implies a withdrawal from such means from civil society. In civil society these means are relatively scarce with regard to occurring needs. Therefore, it can be said that means of production in the armed forces are also scarce. The output of the armed forces may be provided outside a market regime, however in regards to their inputs they are actually taking part in a civilian exchange process. Both on the labour market and on the capital market the armed forces have to satisfy the market demands.

“The larger point is that force structure itself should be a function of the costs of the specific inputs.”

Richard V.L. Cooper in: Military manpower and the All-Volunteer-Force, Santa Monica 1977, pp. 275.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   39.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD   54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Literatur

  1. In other words, because of the conscription tax the social cost of conscripts is far above the real cost.

    Google Scholar 

  2. For a general theoretical background see: A. Koutsoyiannis, Modern Microeconomics, London 1975.

    Google Scholar 

  3. See chapter 6, paragraph 1.

    Google Scholar 

  4. Research by AVNM: Verveling in dienst, Utrecht 1989

    Google Scholar 

  5. For 33.570 approved boys, you need 45.987 tested boys, because only 73% gets through. The wage that is needed to get the last well-tested boy in to the armed forces is / 17.684 net a year. For calculations see appendix 5.1.

    Google Scholar 

  6. See for calculation: Appendix 5.1.

    Google Scholar 

  7. Richard V.L. Cooper, Military Manpower and the All-Volunteer Force, Santa Monica, 1977, pp. 286.

    Google Scholar 

  8. This paragraph is based on: M. Binkin, The Military Pay Muddle, The Brookings Institution, Washington DC, 1975;

    Google Scholar 

  9. M. Binkin, H. Kanter and R.H. Clark, Shaping the defense civilian work force, The Brookings Institution, Washington DC, 1978, and

    Google Scholar 

  10. Stichting Maatschappij and Krijgsmacht, The price of defense, The Hague, 1983.

    Google Scholar 

  11. See parliamentary question nr 207 and 211, Tweede Kamer, Vergaderjaar 1990–1991,2199IX, nr. 8. The amount of combat positions for the Navy and the Air Force are estimated on the basis of the Defensienota 1991. The amount of marines is put at 3.000 and for the personnel on the ships (including relief) a ship-shore ratio of 3:7 counts. This ratio is well known in the United States. All other figures are based on the Defensienota 1991. The background of the number in training of 1.500 is given in paragraph 5.6.

    Google Scholar 

  12. The amount of military should be diminished to 86.696 in 1995 on a total of 107.573. Source Defensienota 1991. Because of the Prioriteitennota 1993 these figures are out of date now, but this is not relevant for a analysis of conscription.

    Google Scholar 

  13. See chapter 2, paragraph 2.

    Google Scholar 

  14. See for extension of this problem: chapter 7.

    Google Scholar 

  15. Charles Moskos, L’armee de metier Americaine (1973–1990): Constat de carence; Fondation pour les etudes de defense nationale, Paris, February 1991.

    Google Scholar 

  16. Gay, Robert M., Estimating the cost of on-the-job training in military occupation: A methodology and pilot study, The Rand Corporation, Santa Monica 1974.

    Google Scholar 

  17. Committee Mommersteeg, Verplicht of vrijwillig dienen, Den Haag 1976.

    Google Scholar 

  18. Zie footnote 14.

    Google Scholar 

  19. See table 5.2. In 1992 the Netherlands had 51,.651 professionals

    Google Scholar 

  20. In 1992 the armed forces needed 4,550 professional military each year to fill their positions on 51 ,.000 positions totally. This means that in an armed forces with 35.,00 professional military positions, about 3.000 positions have to filled each year.

    Google Scholar 

  21. Civilians 37,000 x 65,848 = 2,436 million guilders, military: 35,000 x 70,461 = 2,466 million guilders.

    Google Scholar 

  22. Civilians: 37,000 x 65,848 = 2,436 million guilders, military: 35,000 x 74,797 = 2,617 million guilders.

    Google Scholar 

  23. Military: 99,000 x 68,730 = 6,804 million guilders + civilians 25,800 x 65,848 = 1,698 million guilders.

    Google Scholar 

  24. Military: 45,00 x 74,797 = 3,336 million guilders + civilians 48,000 x 65,848 = 3,161 million guilders.

    Google Scholar 

  25. (99,000 – 45,000)799,000 = 0.55

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 1999 Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Duindam, S. (1999). Conscription and the allocation of production factors. In: Military Conscription. Contributions to Economics. Physica, Heidelberg. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-50005-3_5

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-50005-3_5

  • Publisher Name: Physica, Heidelberg

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-7908-1203-9

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-642-50005-3

  • eBook Packages: Springer Book Archive

Publish with us

Policies and ethics