Skip to main content

Part of the book series: Lecture Notes in Economics and Mathematical Systems ((LNE,volume 321))

Abstract

When David M. Gordon introduced the term “social structure of accumulation” in the late 1970s he pointedly focused the attention of economists and historians on the social nature of long term economic fluctuations.1 As he and his later co-authors put it, we may mark the passage from one distinct period of capitalist growth to another more insightfully by the bunching of institutional innovations then by the bunching of technological innovations. Those who have followed Gordon (including the present writer) have thus shown more interest in the emergence of collective bargaining and the growth of the welfare state than in the development of the automobile, plastics and the computer.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Works Cited

  • Michel Aglietta, A Theory of Economic Regulation: The U.S. Experience. (London: New Left Books, 1979).

    Google Scholar 

  • Kenneth Arrow, “Economic Welfare and the Allocation of Reaourcaes for Invention,” in The Rate and Direction of Inventive Activity, (New York: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1962) 609–625.

    Google Scholar 

  • Simon Avenell, “Technical Change and Commodity Relations,” (University of Massachusetts doctoral dissertation in progress, 1988.)

    Google Scholar 

  • John H. Barton, “The Internatinoal Breeders Rights System and Crop Plant Innovation,” Science 216, (June 4, 1982), 1071–1075.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jean-Pierre Berlan and Richard Lewontin, “Breeders Rights and Patenting Life Forms,” Nature, 322 (August 28, 1986), 785–788.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jean-Pierre Berlan and Richard Lewontin, “Hybrid Corn and the Unsettled Question of Technical Change,” mimeo, May, 1985.

    Google Scholar 

  • Amit Bhaduri, “A Study in Agricultural Backwardness under Semi-Feudalism,” Economic Journal, 83 (1973), 120–137.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Samuel Bowies and Herbert Gintis, “Contested Exchange: Political Economy and Modern Economic Theory,” American Economic Review, May, 1988.

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuel Bowles, Peter Dixon and David Kendrick, Notes and Problems in Microeconomic Theory, (Chicago: Markham, 1971).

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuel Bowles, “The Production Process in a Competitive Economy: Walrasian, Marxian, and NeoHobbesian Models,” American Economic Review, 75,1 (March 1985), 16–36.

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuel Bowies, David Gordon, and Thomas Weisskopf, “Power and Profits: The Social Structure of Accumulation and the Profitability of the Postwar United States Economy,” Review of Radical Political Economics, 18:1&2, 132–167 (Spring and Summer, 1986).

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuel Bowles, David Gordon, and Thomas Weisskopf, “Business Ascendency and Economic Impasse: A Structural Retrospective on Conservative Economica, 1979–1987,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, Fall, 1988.

    Google Scholar 

  • Robert Boyer, La Theorie De La Regulation: Un Analyse Critique (Paris, La Decouverte, 1986).

    Google Scholar 

  • Robert Boyer and Jacques Mistral, Accumulation, Inflation, et Crise, (Paris: PUF 1978).

    Google Scholar 

  • Harry Braverman, Labor and Monopoly Capital, (New York: Monthly Review Press, 1974).

    Google Scholar 

  • Martin Brown and Peter Philips, “The Historical Origin of Job Ladders in the U.S. Canning Industry, and Their Effects on the Gender Division of Labour,” Cambridge Journal of Economics, 10 (1986), 129–145.

    Google Scholar 

  • Murray Brown, On the Theory and Measurement of Technological Change, (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1966)

    Google Scholar 

  • Robert Dorfman, Prices and Markets. (New York: Prentice Hall, 1967).

    Google Scholar 

  • Richard C. Edwards, Contested Terrain: The Transformation of the Workolace in the 20th Century, (New York: Basic Books, 1979).

    Google Scholar 

  • Herbert Gintis, “Savings, Investment, and the Interest Rate: Credit Rationing in Competitive Equilibrium,” mimeo, University of Massachusetts, 1988.

    Google Scholar 

  • David Gordon, “Stages of Accumulation and Long Economic Swings,” in T. Hopkins and I Wallerstein, eds., Processes of the World-System (Sage Publications, 1980).

    Google Scholar 

  • Zvi Griliches, “Research Costs and Social Returns: Hybrid Corn and Related Innovations,” Journal of Political Economy, October, 1958, 419–431.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aljean Harmetz, “Film Industry Escalates War Against Pirates,” New York Times, June 23, 1986.

    Google Scholar 

  • William Lazonick, “Industrial Relatons and Technical Change: The Case of the Self-Acting Mule,” Cambridge Journal of Economics, 3 (1979), 231–62.

    Google Scholar 

  • Abba Lerner, “The Economics and Politics of Consumer Sovereignty,” American Economic Review, 62 (1972).

    Google Scholar 

  • Alain Lipietz, Crise et Inflation, Pourquoi?, (Paris: 1979).

    Google Scholar 

  • Stephen Marglin, “What Do Bosses Do?” Review of Radical Political Economics, 1974.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gary Marx and Sanford Sherizen, “Monitoring on the Job,” Technology Review, 89, 8 (November–December, 1986), 62–72.

    Google Scholar 

  • Karl Marx, Capital, Volume I, (New York, International Publishers, 1967).

    Google Scholar 

  • 9to5, National Association of Working Women, “Computer Monitoring and Other Dirty Tricks,” mimeo, 1986

    Google Scholar 

  • David Noble, “Automation Madness, or the Unautomatic History of Automation,” mimeo, n.d.

    Google Scholar 

  • Paul Samuelson, “Wages and Interest: A Modern Dissection of Marxian Economics,” American Economic Review, 47 (1957).

    Google Scholar 

  • Juliet Schor and Samuel Bowles, “Employment Rents and Incidence of Strikes,” Review of Economics and Statistics, LXIX, 4, 584–592 (November, 1987).

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • “Sound Piratea: A War of One-upmanahip,” Buaineaa Week, March 16, 1981, p. 40p.

    Google Scholar 

  • Katherine Stone, “The Origin of Job Structures in the Steel Industry,” Review of Radical Political Economics, 1974.

    Google Scholar 

  • Daniel Yankelovich and John Immerwahr, “Putting the Work Ethic to Work,” Society, January–February, 1984, 58–76.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 1989 Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg

About this paper

Cite this paper

Bowles, S. (1989). Social Institutions and Technical Change. In: Di Matteo, M., Goodwin, R.M., Vercelli, A. (eds) Technological and Social Factors in Long Term Fluctuations. Lecture Notes in Economics and Mathematical Systems, vol 321. Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-48360-8_5

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-48360-8_5

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-540-50663-8

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-642-48360-8

  • eBook Packages: Springer Book Archive

Publish with us

Policies and ethics