Skip to main content

Generic Structure to Simulate Acceptance Dynamics

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Dynamic Governance of Energy Technology Change

Part of the book series: Sustainability and Innovation ((SUSTAINABILITY))

  • 1082 Accesses

Abstract

Social behaviour patterns and social equilibrium states are often guided by stable values such as social norms. However, changing environmental conditions (e.g. climate warming, resource scarcity) may require behavioural change and the acceptance of new technologies. Antecedents of aggregate behavioural change are value changes that predetermine when new behaviour patterns emerge and a new social equilibrium state can be reached. The paper addresses these phenomena. First, based on a waste recycling model, we explain these phenomena and develop a simple, generic mathematical model describing the basic traits of acceptance-rejection dynamics. Second, we propose a generic model structure for the simulation of acceptance-rejection behaviour that represents the dynamical characteristics of paradigm change processes. We show that a fourth-order potential function is a sine qua non for an adequate representation of a paradigm change. Third, we also explain why the well-known Bass model, is unable to capture acceptance and rejection dynamics.

Reprinted from Ulli-Beer et al (2010) Generic structure to simulate acceptance dynamics. Syst Dyn Rev 26(2):89–116. With kind permission from John Wiley & Sons, Inc., Nov. 2012.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. 1.

    The unit equation of the first equation in Eq. 8.2 is the following: kg/s · m/s = mkg/s2. α is the friction parameter with the units kg/s. In the following, we set this parameter to unity being dimensionless. Therefore, the units of velocity and force become identical.

  2. 2.

    To make the two potentials identical, an additional linear transformation of the x-coordinate and a vertical translation would be necessary. These transformations are not relevant and are therefore omitted.

  3. 3.

    Relations (B-1) are an approximation for small slopes. For an infinite slope, the force according to (B-1) becomes infinite, in contrast to the physical force for the free fall being -mg. However, this discrepancy for steep slopes does not disturb our metaphor, because in real applications, slopes are normally small.

References

  • Ajzen I (1991) The theory of planned behavior. Organ Behav Hum Decis Process 50:179–211

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ajzen I, Fishbein M (1980) Understanding attitudes and predicting social behavior. Englewood Cliffs, Prentice Hall

    Google Scholar 

  • Argyris C, Schoen DA (1978) Organizational learning: a theory of action perspective. Addision Wesley, Reading

    Google Scholar 

  • Argyris C, Schoen DA (1996) Oranizational learning ll: theory, method, and practice. Addison-Wesley, Reading

    Google Scholar 

  • Bass FM, Jain D et al (2000) Modeling the marketing-mix influence in new-product diffusion. In: Mahajan V, Muller E, Wind Y (eds) New-product diffusion models. Kluwer Academic, Boston

    Google Scholar 

  • Dahlstrand U, Biel A (1997) Pro-environmental habits: propensity levels in behavioral change. J Appl Soc Psychol 27:588–601

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dörner D (1980) On the difficulties people have in dealing with complexity. Simul Games 11(1):87–106

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dörner D (1993) Denken und Handeln in Unbestimmtheit und Komplexität. GAIA 2(3):128–138

    Google Scholar 

  • Dosi G (1982) Technological paradigms and technological trajectories: a suggested interpretation of the determinants and directions of technical change. Res Policy 11:147–162

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dykman MI, Luchinsky DG et al (1995) Stochastic resonance in perspective. Nuovo Cimento D17:661–683

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gassmann F (1997) Noise-induced chaos-order transitions. Phys Rev E55:2215–2221

    Google Scholar 

  • Gassmann FS, Ulli-Beer et al (2006) Acceptance Dynamics. In: Proceedings of the 24th international conference of the system dynamics society, Nijmegen, 23–27 July

    Google Scholar 

  • Janssen A, Lienin SF et al (2006) Model aided policy development for the market penetration of natural gas vehicles in Switzerland. Transp Res A 40:316–333

    Google Scholar 

  • Kaufmann R, Bättig C et al (2001) A typologie of tools for building sustainability strategies. In: Kaufmann-Hayoz R, Gutscher H (eds) Changing things- moving people. Strategies for promoting sustainable development at the local level. Birkhäuser, Basel

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Kuhn T (1962) The structure of scientific revolutions. University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Mathieson K (1991) Predicting user intentions: comparing the technology acceptance model with the theory of planned behavior. Inf Syst Res 2:173–191

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Paich M (1985) Generic structures. Syst Dyn Rev 1(1):126–132

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rahn RJ (1985) Aggregation in system dynamics. Syst Dyn Rev 1(1):111–122

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rasmussen S, Mosekilde E et al (1985) Bifurcations and chaotic behavior in a simple model of the economic long wave. Syst Dyn Rev 1(1):92–110

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sterman JD (2000) Business dynamics. Systems thinking and modeling for a complex world. Irwin McGraw-Hill, Boston

    Google Scholar 

  • Struben J, Sterman JD (2008) Transition challenges for alternative fuel vehicle and transportation systems. Environ Plann B Plann Design 35:1070–1097

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sutera A (1981) On stochastic perturbation and long-term climate behavior. Q J R Meterol Soc 107:137–153

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Train KE (2003) Discret choice methods with simulation. Cambridge Univ Press, Cambridge, UK

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Ulli-Beer S (2006) Citizens’ choice and public policy: a system dynamics model for recycling management at the local level. Shaker Verlag, Aachen

    Google Scholar 

  • Ulli-Beer S, Richardson GP et al (2004) A SD-choice structure for policy compliance: micro behavior explaining aggregated recycling dynamics. In: Proceedings of the 22nd international conference of the system dynamics society, Oxford, 25–29 July 2004

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We thank David Andersen for guiding advice. Ruth Kaufmann-Hayoz, Susanne Bruppacher and Stefan Grösser gave us helpful input at a lively seminar discussion. Three anonymous reviewers helped to improve our work with constructive comments. Mohammad Mojtahedzadeh pointed us to further relevant and helpful work conducted in the field of System Dynamics. Financial support is given to our project from novatlantis, a sustainability project of the Board of ETH Zürich.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Silvia Ulli-Beer .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 Generic Structure of the Waste Recycling Model

The 50 parameters and 33 nonlinear functions of the original waste recycling model have been reduced to the two parameters P and τR, and the two functions f(x) and g(y) with the following meanings:

  • P = overall population

  • X = number of adopters

  • Y = number of non-adopters

  • τR = time to adjust

  • f(x) = influence of the adopters’ norm on non-adopters

  • g(y) = influence of the non-adopters’ norm on adopters

The dynamical equations of the simplified model are

$$ \begin{array}{l}\frac{ dx}{ dt}=p\left(x,y\right)-q\left(x,y\right)\\ {}\frac{ dy}{ dt}=q\left(x,y\right)-p\left(x,y\right)\end{array} $$
(8.6)

with the condition

$$ P=x+y $$
(8.7)

and the two functions being defined by

$$ \begin{array}{l}p\left(x,y\right)=\frac{f(x)/P}{\tau_R}y\\ {}q\left(x,y\right)=\frac{g(y)/P}{\tau_R}x\end{array} $$
(8.8)

The two dynamical Eq. 8.6 for the two population groups x and y, together with the condition Eq. 8.7, can be expressed by one dynamical equation for x, describing the balance of the adoption rate p(x,y) and the frustration rate q(x,y). These two rates are defined symmetrically with the functions f(x) and g(y), and involve the time constant τR Eq. 8.8. The influence f(x) of the adopters’ norm on non-adopters vanishes for x = 0, because there is no adopters’ norm established without adopters. With only a few adopters, their influence is still negligible, suggesting a horizontal tangent f’(0) = 0. With an increasing number of adopters, however, their influence becomes important. The most simple functions f(x), and analogously g(y), which fulfil these three conditions, are quadratic polynomials:

$$ \begin{array}{l}f(x)={\nu}_1\cdot {x}^2\\ {}g(y)={\nu}_2\cdot {y}^2\end{array} $$
(8.9)

The two new parameters ν1 and ν2 describe the strength of the effect of the adopters’ norm and the non-adopters’ norm, respectively. We apply the following normalisation to further simplify the equations:

$$ \begin{array}{l}{x}^{\prime }=\frac{x}{P}\\ {}{y}^{\prime }=\frac{y}{P}=1-{x}^{\prime}\\ {}{\nu}_1^{\prime }=P\cdot {\nu}_1\\ {}{\nu}_2^{\prime }=P\cdot {\nu}_2\end{array} $$
(8.10)

With the substitutions Eq. 8.10, the dynamical Eq. 8.6 take a simple form. For the sake of convenience, the dashes are omitted in the following:

$$ \frac{ dx}{ dt}=\frac{\nu_1+{\nu}_2}{\tau_R}x\;\left(1-x\right)\;\left(x-\frac{\nu_2}{\nu_1+{\nu}_2}\;\right) $$
(8.11)

Equation 8.11 can be transformed into the following elegant form including a potential V(x):

$$ \frac{ dx}{ dt}=-\frac{ dV(x)}{ dx} $$
(8.12)

With the potential V(x) according to Eq. 8.13, the generalised Eq. 8.12 becomes identical to the special dynamics Eq. 8.11:

$$ V(x)=\frac{1}{12{\tau}_R}{x}^2\;\left\{6{\nu}_2-4\;\left({\nu}_1+2{\nu}_2\right)\;x+3\;\left({\nu}_1+{\nu}_2\right)\;{x}^2\right\} $$
(8.13)

This double-well potential (a polynomial of fourth order) has the following extremes:

$$ \begin{array}{c}V(0)=0\\ {}V(1)=\frac{\nu_2-{\nu}_1}{12{\tau}_R}\\ {}V\left(\frac{\nu_2}{\nu_1+{\nu}_2}\right)=\frac{1}{12{\tau}_R}{\left(\frac{\nu_2}{\nu_1+{\nu}_2}\right)}^3\left(2{\nu}_1+{\nu}_2\right)\end{array} $$
(8.14)

The first two extremes at x = 0 and x = 1 are stable minima and the third is an unstable maximum in between. In general, the potential Eq. 8.13 is asymmetric, because the minimum at x = 1 is above or below the x-axis, if ν2 is larger or smaller than ν1, respectively. For the special symmetric case ν1 = ν2 = ν, the extremes Eq. 8.14 of the potential Eq. 8.13 simplify to:

$$ \begin{array}{c}V(0)=0\\ {}V(1)=0\\ {}V\left(\frac{1}{2}\right)=\frac{1}{32{\tau}_R/\nu}\end{array} $$
(8.15)

The graph of this symmetric double-well potential is shown in Fig. 8.4 in the main text. Within the framework of the waste recycling model, the variable x (percentage of adopters) is confined to the interval between 0 and 1. To make the stable minima better visible, the potential V(x) is given for an extended x-range.

Our analysis shows that at least one of the two functions f(x) and g(1 − x), describing the effect of the perceived social norms, must be nonlinear to be able to lead to two simultaneously stable minima of the potential V(x). If both functions are assumed to be linear, the respective potential is a third-order polynomial with only one global minimum at x = 0 or at x = 1 (y = 1 − x) for the slope of f being smaller or larger than the slope of g, respectively. For this case with linear functions f and g, the basic character of the system would be different: As soon as the effect of the adopters’ norm had a larger slope than the effect of the non-adopters’ norm, the system would undergo a transient from x = 0 (not recycling) to x = 1 (recycling), without any external force (garbage bag charge) needed. For the case that the slope of the effect of the adopters’ norm would be smaller compared to that of the non-adopters’ norm, a garbage bag charge would push the system towards x = 1, but no paradigm change would occur, stabilising this state: As soon as the charge were relieved, the system would fall back to x = 0. This analysis demonstrates that one of the most important decisions during the modelling process is the choice of the shape of the norm-functions f and g. In the model validation process, observational evidence suggesting linear or nonlinear norm functions would therefore be of prime importance.

Another remark concerns the discrepancy of the numbers of parameters and functions between the full model and the simplified generic model. In every model useful for practical purposes, a large number of parameters are needed, because the important effective parameters (in our case τR, ν1 and ν2) must be related to practically relevant input parameters. The strength of the generic model, however, is not its application to simulate observed processes, but to help us understand its basic behaviour and to give us an idea of its solution manifold. It contains only a very limited number of effective parameters and functions, and thus shows us the relevant combinations of parameters and functions defining the trajectories to be expected.

1.2 The Light-Ball Metaphor

We consider a light air-inflated plastic ball with mass m moving downhill with velocity u. Its dynamics can be formulated with the notion of potential energy V(x) (in the physical literature, V(x) is called gravitational potential) in the following way:

$$ \begin{array}{c}V(x)=m\cdot g\cdot h(x)\\ {}m\cdot \frac{ du}{ dt}\approx -\frac{ dV}{ dx}-\alpha \cdot u\;\\ {}u\equiv \frac{ dx}{ dt}\;\end{array} $$
(8.16)

where g is the gravitational acceleration, t is time, and h(x) describes the height of a graph of the potential function V(x) with one horizontal dimension x. Multiplication of the slope dh/dx by -mg gives the force -dV/dx accelerating the ball downhill.Footnote 3 The term -α · u describes the frictional braking force of the air (according to Stokes’ law, this frictional force is proportional to velocity u). Our experience tells us that such a light ball, after a short initial acceleration phase, rolls downhill at a constant speed, only depending on the slope. To simplify our dynamics Eq. 8.16, we therefore neglect the inertia term by setting

$$ m\cdot \frac{ du}{ dt}=0 $$
(8.17)

and find the approximate dynamics:

$$ u=-\frac{ dV}{ dx} $$
(8.18)

The parameter α has been set to unity because it does not affect the character of the solutions of Eq. 8.18. In the physical literature, this approximation is called overdamped limit, because the respective system approaches an equilibrium point gradually rather than with damped oscillations. This property can be demonstrated, e.g., for the equilibrium point in a quadratic potential V = x 2 situated at x = 0. Introducing this most simple nonlinear potential into Eq. 8.18 gives

$$ u\equiv \frac{ dx}{ dt}=-\frac{d}{ dx}{x}^2=-2x $$
(8.19)

with the solution

$$ x(t)={x}_0{e}^{-2t} $$
(8.20)

where x0 is the initial position of the ball and t is time. Equation 8.20 describes a trajectory approaching the equilibrium point x = 0 gradually, without oscillations. Mathematically, the ball would need an infinite amount of time to reach x = 0, but for practical applications, t = 3 is already sufficient, giving a distance to zero of less than 1 % of the initial value x0.

For a multistable system, we need at least two stable equilibria, described by a double-well potential V(x). A simple form of such a potential is a polynomial of fourth order:

$$ \begin{array}{l}V(x)=a{x}^2\left\{{x}^2-2{\mu}^2\right\}\\ {}-\frac{ dV}{ dx}=-4 ax\left\{{x}^2-{\mu}^2\right\}\end{array} $$
(8.21)

To prevent the ball escaping to infinity, we assume a ≥ 0. At x = 0, we find an unstable equilibrium, and two locally stable equilibria are located at x = ±μ. Combined with Eq. 8.18, we get the following dynamics:

$$ \frac{ dx}{ dt}=-4 ax\left\{{x}^2-{\mu}^2\right\} $$
(8.22)

To assign simple meanings to the two parameters a and μ, we define two new parameters τ and η (their meanings will be explained below):

$$ \begin{array}{l}\tau =\frac{1}{8a{\mu}^2}\\ {}\eta =a{\mu}^4\end{array} $$
(8.23)

and write the dynamics Eqs. 8.21 and 8.22 with these new parameters:

$$ \begin{array}{l}\frac{ dx}{ dt}=\frac{x}{2\tau}\left\{1-\frac{x^2}{8\tau \eta}\right\}+F(t)\\ {}V(x)=\frac{x^2}{8\tau}\left\{\frac{x^2}{8\tau \eta}-2\right\}\end{array} $$
(8.24)

In addition, an external force F(t) has been introduced. The stable equilibria (with F = 0) are now located at

$$ {x}_s=\pm \sqrt{8\tau \eta} $$

The parameter η is the height of the “activation potential” (e.g. the unstable equilibrium) with its top at xu = 0 lying in between the two stable equilibria at xs, as can easily be verified:

$$ V\left({x}_u\right)-V\left({x}_s\right)=0-\frac{8\tau \eta}{8\tau}\left\{\frac{8\tau \eta}{8\tau \eta}-2\right\}=\eta $$
(8.25)

τ is the endogenous time constant of the system near its stable equilibria xs. This can be verified by linearisation of the dynamics around xs. To this aim, we replace x with the new coordinate ξ, being the distance from xs:

$$ \xi =x-{x}_s $$
(8.26)

After introducing Eq. 8.26 into Eq. 8.24, we linearise the dynamics for small ξ and get the approximate differential equation for the trajectory in the neighbourhood of the stable equilibria

$$ \frac{ d\xi}{ d t}\approx -\frac{1}{\tau}\xi $$
(8.27)

with the solutions

$$ \xi (t)\approx {\xi}_0{e}^{-\frac{t}{\tau }} $$
(8.28)

ξ0 is the initial position of the ball at t = 0. By definition, τ is the time constant for the relaxation of the system to its equilibrium point ξ = 0, which had to be shown.

For a graphical representation of the potential V(x) according to Eq. 8.24 for τ = η = 1, see Fig. 8.7 in the main text.

1.3 Light-Ball System Response to Transient Forces

1.3.1 Small Transient Forces

We apply a small constant force F0 and ask for the deviation δ from the force-free equilibrium point at position xs = −(8ητ)1/2:

$$ \delta =x+\sqrt{8\tau \eta} $$
(8.29)

We substitute x in Eq. 8.24 by δ according to Eq. 8.29 and ask for the stationary solution by setting the time derivative to zero. This leads to the following relation between F0 and δ:

$$ \delta \left\{{\delta}^2-3\delta \sqrt{8\tau \eta}+16\tau \eta \right\}=16{\tau}^2\eta {F}_0 $$
(8.30)

For small δ, the bracket in Eq. 8.30 reduces to the constant term and we get approximately:

$$ \delta \approx {F}_0\cdot \tau $$
(8.31)

An example for a dynamical simulation with F0 = 0.1 is given in Fig. 8.10. Note that the bracket of Eq. 8.30 reads for τ = η = 1 and δ = 0.1: (0.01 − 0.85 + 16). Clearly, the first two terms are negligible compared to the constant third term!

Fig. 8.10
figure 10

Trajectory beginning at the left equilibrium (xs = −2.828) for a constant external force F0 = 0.1 in the time interval t = 0…10. For t > 10, F0 = 0 is assumed. After a few τ have elapsed, a new equilibrium position is found with a distance δ from the stable force-free equilibrium point. The simulated δ is 0.105, as indicated by the double arrow. The approximation Eq. 8.31 gives δ = 0.100, only 5 % smaller than the simulated δ.

The internal time constant τ of the system is identical to the proportionality constant mediating between an applied small external force and the resulting deviation δ according to Eq. 8.31. To prove this generic result, we approximate an arbitrary potential V(x) around one of its minima by a second-order polynomial:

$$ V\left(\xi \right)=\frac{\xi^2}{2\tau } $$
(8.32)

with the coordinate ξ being the distance from the respective minimum. From the dynamic equation

$$ \frac{ d\xi}{ d t}=-\frac{ d V}{ d\xi}+{F}_0=-\frac{\xi }{\tau }+{F}_0 $$
(8.33)

with the solution

$$ \xi (t)={\xi}_0\cdot {e}^{-\frac{t}{\tau }} $$
(8.34)

for F0 = 0, we immediately find the first meaning of τ being the system-internal relaxation time constant. From the same dynamical Eq. 8.33, we get the deviation δ of the equilibrium point for small forces F0

$$ \frac{ d\xi}{ d t}=0=-\frac{\delta }{\tau }+{F}_0 $$
(8.35)

leading directly to Eq. 8.31, where τ has the second meaning as a proportionality constant between an applied small external force and the resulting deviation.

1.3.2 Large Transient Forces

To induce a transition from the left equilibrium point to the right, the transient force F0 must be able to push the ball up the steepest slope of V(x). With the dynamic equation

$$ \begin{array}{l}\frac{ dx}{ dt}=-\frac{ dV}{ dx}+{F}_0\\ {}V(x)=\frac{x^2}{8\tau}\left\{\frac{x^2}{8\tau \eta}-2\right\}\end{array} $$
(8.36)

this first condition is equivalent to

$$ \frac{ dx}{ dt}=-\frac{ dV}{ dx}+{F}_0>0 $$
(8.37)

for the most positive slope of V(x) occurring at xm with

$$ {\left.\frac{d^2V}{d{x}^2}\right|}_{x_m}=0 $$
(8.38)

From Eqs. 8.36 and 8.38, we find

$$ {x}_m=-\sqrt{\frac{8}{3}\tau \eta} $$
(8.39)

leading with Eq. 8.37 to the first necessary condition

$$ {F}_0>\sqrt{\frac{8}{27}\frac{\eta }{\tau }} $$
(8.40)

Another condition to induce a transition refers to the duration T of the force F0. For the best case of a flat potential V(x) = 0, Eq. 8.37 defines a constant velocity dx/dt = u = F0. With this velocity u, the system state must travel at least from the left equilibrium point to zero during T, giving the second necessary condition

$$ u\cdot T={F}_0\cdot T>\sqrt{8\tau \eta} $$
(8.41)

1.4 Bass Dynamics with the Light-Ball Model

We define the system state x of the light-ball model as the number of items sold until time t and concentrate on the portion of the potential V(x) between x = 0 and x = xs + F0τ (xs = positive stable equilibrium for F0 = 0). The system dynamics with small external force F0 > 0, according to Eqs. 8.2 or 8.24, is the following:

$$ \frac{ dx}{ dt}=\frac{x}{2\tau}\left\{1-\frac{x^2}{8\tau \eta}\right\}+{F}_0 $$
(8.42)

For small x, Eq. 8.42 reduces to dx/dt = F0 leading to a linear growth of x. At larger x, for x 2 < < 8τη and F0 < < x/(2τ), we find approximately an exponential growth of x with time constant 2τ:

$$ x(t)\approx {x}_0{e}^{\frac{t}{2\tau }} $$
(8.43)

For xm with maximum slope of V(x), F0 can be neglected and we find:

$$ \begin{array}{l}{x}_m\approx \sqrt{\frac{8\tau \eta}{3}}\\ {}\frac{ dx}{ dt}\approx \sqrt{\frac{8\eta }{27\tau }}\end{array} $$
(8.44)

Finally, for x near the equilibrium xs + F0τ, we find an exponential approximation with time constant τ according to Eq. 8.27.

The Bass model is generally presented in the following form:

$$ \frac{f(t)}{1-F(t)}=p+ qF(t) $$
(8.45)

where f(t) stands for the sale rate of a product and F(t) for the total amount of items sold until time point t. p is called coefficient of innovation and q is the coefficient of imitation. If we use the relation f = dF/dt, we can write the Bass model in the form:

$$ \frac{ dF}{ dt}=\left(p+ qF\right)\left(1-F\right) $$
(8.46)

For small F (near t = 0), the dynamics reduces to

$$ \frac{ dF}{ dt}\equiv f\approx p $$
(8.47)

giving a constant sale rate f = p and a linear increase of the total amount F of items sold. For a time interval, where qF > > p and F << 1, the approximate dynamics are

$$ \frac{ dF}{ dt}\equiv f\approx qF $$
(8.48)

leading to an exponential growth of both, F and f with time constant 1/q:

$$ \begin{array}{l}F(t)\approx {F}_0{e}^{qt}\\ {}f(t)\approx q{F}_0{e}^{qt}\end{array} $$
(8.49)

The maximum slope of F (maximum selling rate f) is found from Eq. 8.46 at Fm lying near 50 % of the ultimate market potential (which is normalised to 1) for the majority of situations characterised by p << q:

$$ \begin{array}{l}{F}_m=\frac{1}{2}\left(1-\frac{p}{q}\right)\approx \frac{1}{2}\\ {}{f}_m\approx \frac{q}{4}\end{array} $$
(8.50)

For F near to unity, we find from the approximated dynamics

$$ \frac{ dF}{ dt}\approx q\left(1-F\right) $$
(8.51)

the trajectory

$$ F(t)\approx 1-{e}^{- qt} $$
(8.52)

i.e., an exponential approximation of the ultimate market potential with a time constant 1/q.

By comparing each of the three phases (initial linear growth, exponential growth, final exponential approximation of the ultimate market potential) described by the two different models, we find the following equivalences:

  • By definition

    $$ \mathrm{F}=\mathrm{x} $$
  • Following from the definition

    $$ \mathrm{f}=\mathrm{u}=\mathrm{dx}/\mathrm{dt} $$
  • xs + F0τ = 1 and xs 2 = 8τη

    $$ \eta \approx \frac{{\left(1-{F}_0\tau \right)}^2}{8\tau } $$
  • Equation D-1 for small x compared with Eq. 8.47

    $$ \mathrm{p}={\mathrm{F}}_0 $$
  • Time constant τ from Eq. 8.27 compared with Eq. 8.52

    $$ \mathrm{q}=1/\uptau $$

It should be added here that the two models could be made exactly identical by replacing the fourth-order potential Eq. 8.24 of the ball model with the third-order potential

$$ V(x)=\frac{x}{\tau}\left\{\frac{x^2}{3}-\frac{x}{2}\left(1-{F}_0\tau \right)-{F}_0\tau \right\} $$
(8.53)

Here, F0 would no longer be an external force, but an additional parameter shaping the potential V(x). Equation 8.53 is proven to be correct by the substitutions x → F, 1/τ → q, F0 → p and comparing dF/dt = −dV(F)/dF with Eq. 8.46.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2013 Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Ulli-Beer, S., Gassmann, F., Bosshardt, M., Wokaun, A. (2013). Generic Structure to Simulate Acceptance Dynamics. In: Ulli-Beer, S. (eds) Dynamic Governance of Energy Technology Change. Sustainability and Innovation. Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-39753-0_8

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-39753-0_8

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-642-39752-3

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-642-39753-0

  • eBook Packages: Business and EconomicsEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics