Advertisement

Using a Structural Equation Model to Analyze Potential Determinants of Spatial Variations in Endogenous Regional Growth Performance

  • Patricio ArocaEmail author
  • Robert Stimson
  • Roger Stough
Chapter
Part of the Advances in Spatial Science book series (ADVSPATIAL)

Abstract

There have been relatively few attempts to develop operational models explicitly designed to measure endogenous regional economic performance and to identify those factors that potentially might explain spatial variations in that performance across a national space economy. This chapter does that by experimenting with structural equation modelling as an alternative to the commonly used ordinary least square (OLS) regression modelling.

Keywords

Social Capital Human Capital Structural Equation Modelling Ordinary Less Square Endogenous Growth 
These keywords were added by machine and not by the authors. This process is experimental and the keywords may be updated as the learning algorithm improves.

Notes

Acknowledgements

The research on which this chapter relates to a broader program of research into modelling endogenous regional economic performance supported by the Australian Research Council (grant# DP0879819), Nucleus of the Millennium Science Initiative Program “Regional Sciences and Public Policy” (from Ministry of Economics, Chile), FONDECYT project # 1111061, Chile, and the George Mason University Foundation in the U.S.

References

  1. Amin A, Thrift N (1995) Globalisation, institutional “thickness” and the local economy. In: Healey P, Cameron PS, Davaoudi S, Graham S, Madani-Pour A (eds) Managing cities: the new urban context. Wiley, Chichester/New York, pp 92–108Google Scholar
  2. Anselin L (1988a) Spatial econometrics: methods and models. Kluwer, LondonCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. Anselin L (1988b) Model validation in spatial econometrics: a review and evaluation of alternative approaches. Int Reg Sci Rev 11:279–316CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Arrow KJ (1962) The economic implications of learning by doing. Rev Econ Stud 29:155–173CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Arthur WB (1994) Increasing returns and path dependency in the economy. University of Michigan Press, Ann ArborGoogle Scholar
  6. Barro RJ (1990) Government spending in a simple model of endogenous growth. J Polit Econ 98:S103–S125CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. Barros R, Broadbent RA, Cordey-Hayes M, Massey DB, Robinson K, Willis J (1971) An operational urban development model for Cheshire. Environ Plan 3:115–234CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Bentley J (2002) New wines in old bottles: the challenge of developing leaders. In: Derr B, Rousillon S, Bournois F (eds) Latin America. Cross cultural approaches to leadership development. Quorum, WestportGoogle Scholar
  9. Bollen KA, Bauer DJ, Christ SL (2010) Overview of structural equation modeling. In: Kolenikov S, Steinley D, Thombs L (eds) Statistics in the social sciences. Wiley, New York, pp 37–78CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Bolton R (1992) ‘Place prosperity’ vs ‘people prosperity’. Urban Stud 29:185–203CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. Bolton R (1999) Place surplus, exit, voice, and loyalty. Uddevalla symposium on evaluation of regional policies, Fiskebackkil, JuneGoogle Scholar
  12. Brooklym C, Bousillon S, Bournois F (eds) (2002) Cross-cultural approaches to leadership. Quorum/Greenwood, WestportGoogle Scholar
  13. Byrne B (2010) Structural equation modeling with AMOS: basic concepts, applications, and programming, 2nd edn. Routledge, LondonGoogle Scholar
  14. Castells M, Hall P (1994) Technopoles of the world: the making of 21st century industrial complexes. Routledge, LondonGoogle Scholar
  15. Capello R, Nijkamp PJ (eds) (2009) Regional growth and development theories in the XXI century: theoretical achievements and future challenges. Edward Elgar, CheltenhamGoogle Scholar
  16. Clingermayer JC, Feiock RC (2001) Institutional constraints and policy choice: an exploration of local government. State University of New York Press, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  17. Coleman J (1988) Social capital in the creation of social capital. Am J Sociol 94:95–120CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  18. de Santis M, Stough RR (1999) Fast adjusting urban regions, leadership and regional economic development. Reg et Dev 10:37–56Google Scholar
  19. Doig J, Hargrove E (1987) Leadership and innovation: a biographical perspective on entrepreneurs in government. John Hopkins University Press, BaltimoreGoogle Scholar
  20. Duranton G, Puga D (2000) Diversity and specialization in cities: why, where and when does it matter. Urban Stud 37:533–555CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. Erickson RA (1994) Technology, industrial restructuring and regional development. Growth Change 25:353–379CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  22. Erickson RA, Leinbach T (1979) Characteristics of branch plants attracted to non metropolitan areas. In: Lonsdale R, Seyter HL (eds) Non metropolitan industrialisation. Winston, Washington, DCGoogle Scholar
  23. Fainstein S (1983) Restructuring the city: the political economy of urban redevelopment. Longman, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  24. Fairholm GW (1994) Leadership and the culture of trust. Praeger, WestportGoogle Scholar
  25. Florida R (1995) Toward the learning region. Futures 27:527–537CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  26. Florida R (2002) The rise of the creative class; and how it’s transforming work, leisure, and everyday life. Basic Books, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  27. Goetz SJ, Rapasingla A (2001) The returns to higher education: estimates for the contiguous states. Paper to Regional Science Association international, North American annual meeting, Charleston, NovemberGoogle Scholar
  28. Gordon IR, McCann P (2000) Industrial clusters, complexes, agglomeration and/or social networks. Urban Stud 373:513–532Google Scholar
  29. Greene WH (2002) Econometric analysis, 5th edn. Prentice Hall, Upper Saddle RiverGoogle Scholar
  30. Grossman GM, Helpman E (1991) Innovation and growth in the global economy. MIT Press, Cambridge, MAGoogle Scholar
  31. Hanushek EA, Kimko DD (2000) Schooling, labour-force quality, and the growth of nations. Am Econ Rev 90:1184–1208CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  32. Heenan DA, Bennis WG (1999) Co-leaders: the power of great partnerships. Wiley, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  33. Hofstede G (ed) (1997) Cultures and organization: software of the mind. McGraw-Hill, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  34. Henderson JV, Kuncoro A, Turner M (1995) Industrial development in cities. J Polit Econ 103:1067–1090CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  35. Huxam C (1996) Collaborative advantage. Sage, Thousand OaksGoogle Scholar
  36. Jessop B (1998) The narrative of enterprise and the enterprise of narrative: place marketing and the entrepreneurial city. In: Hubbard T, Hall PH (eds) The entrepreneurial city. Wiley, Chichester/New York, pp 77–99Google Scholar
  37. Jin DJ, Stough RR (1998) Learning and learning capability in the Fordist and post-Fordist age: an integrative framework. Environ Plan A 30:1255–1278CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  38. Johansson B, Karlsson C, Stough RR (eds) (2001) Theories of endogenous regional growth. Springer, BerlinGoogle Scholar
  39. Kaplan D (2009) Structural equation modeling: foundations and extensions, 2nd edn, Advanced quantitative techniques in the social sciences series. Sage, Los AngelesGoogle Scholar
  40. Kaufman R (1993) An empirical exploration of the relation among diversity, stability and performance in economic systems. Struct Change Econ Dyn 4:299–313CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  41. Kirzner IM (1973) Competition and entrepreneurship. The University of Chicago Press, ChicagoGoogle Scholar
  42. Kline RB (2005) Principles and practice of structural equation modeling, 2nd edn. Guilford, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  43. Krugman P (1991) Geography and trade. MIT Press, Cambridge, MAGoogle Scholar
  44. Lande P (1994) Regional industrial structure and economic growth and stability. J Reg Sci 34:343–360CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  45. Lucas R (1985) Models of business cycles. Basil Blackwell, OxfordGoogle Scholar
  46. Lucas RE (1988) On the mechanics of economic development. J Monet Econ 22:3–42CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  47. Maier G (2001) History, spatial structure, and regional growth: lessons for policy making. In: Johansson B, Karlsson C, Stough RR (eds) Theories of endogenous regional growth. Springer, Heidelberg, pp 255–277Google Scholar
  48. Maillat D, Kibir L (2001) The learning region and territorial production systems. In: Johansson B, Karlsson C, Stough RR (eds) Theories of endogenous regional growth. Springer, Heidelberg, pp 255–277Google Scholar
  49. Malecki E (1991) Technology and economic development: the dynamics of local, regional and national competitiveness. Longman Scientific and Technical, HarlowGoogle Scholar
  50. Malecki E (1998a) How development occurs: local knowledge, social capital, and institutional embeddedness. Paper presented at the annual meeting of the Southern Regional Science Association. SavannahGoogle Scholar
  51. Malecki E (1998b) Technology and economic development: the dynamics of local, regional and national competitiveness. Paper presented to the annual meeting of Southern Regional Science Association, SavannahGoogle Scholar
  52. Markusen A (1985) Profit cycles, oligopoly and regional development. MIT Press, Cambridge, MAGoogle Scholar
  53. Masser I, Brown PJB (1975) Hierarchical aggregation procedures for interaction data. Environ Plan A 7:509–523CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  54. Masser I, Scheurwater J (1980) Functional regionalisation of spatial interaction data: an evaluation of some suggested strategies. Environ Plan A 12:1357–1382CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  55. Mitchell WF, Flanagan M (2009) The CofFEE functional economic regions: first edition. Centre of Full Employment and Equity, NewcastleGoogle Scholar
  56. Norton RD, Rees J (1979) The product cycle and the decentralization of North American manufacturing. Reg Stud 13:141–151CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  57. North D (1990) Institutions, institutional change and economic performance. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  58. OECD (2000) Learning regions and cities: knowledge, learning and regional innovation systems. Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, ParisGoogle Scholar
  59. Oud JHL, Folmer H (2008) A structural equation approach to models with spatial dependence. Geogr Anal 40:152–166CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  60. Parkinson M (1990) Leadership and regeneration in liverpool: confusion, confrontation, or coalition, in Houston. In: Judd and Parkinson (1990), pp 241–257Google Scholar
  61. Patten C (1991) The competitiveness of small firms. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeGoogle Scholar
  62. Pollitt C, Bouckaert G (2002) Public management reform: a comparative analysis. Oxford University Press, OxfordGoogle Scholar
  63. Porter ME (1985) Competitive advantage: creating and sustaining superior performance. Free Press, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  64. Porter ME (1986) Competition in global industries. Harvard Business School Press, Cambridge, MAGoogle Scholar
  65. Porter ME (1990) The competitive advantage of nations. MacMillan, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  66. Putnam R (1993) The prosperous community: social capital and public life. Am Prospect 13(Spring):35–42Google Scholar
  67. Rebelo S (1991) Long run policy analysis and long run growth. J Polit Econ 98:S71–S102Google Scholar
  68. Rees J (1979) State technology programs and industry experience in the USA. Rev Urban Reg Dev Stud 3:39–59CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  69. Rees J (2001) Technology and regional development: theory revisited. In: Johansson B, Karlsson C, Stough RR (eds) Theories of endogenous regional growth. Springer, Heidelberg, pp 94–110CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  70. Rodrick D (1998) TFPG Controversies, institutions and economic performance in Asia. The institutional foundations of East Asian economic development. In: Hayami Y, Aoki M (eds) Proceeding of the IEA conference held in Tokyo, Japan. St. Martin Press in association with the International Economic Association, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  71. Romer PM (1986) Increasing returns and long-run growth. J Polit Econ 94:1002–1037CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  72. Romer PM (1990) Endogenous technological change. J Polit Econ 98:S71–S102CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  73. Saxenian A (1994) Regional advantage: culture and competition in silicon valley and route 128. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MAGoogle Scholar
  74. Schumpeter JA (1934) The theory of economic development. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MAGoogle Scholar
  75. Scott AJ (1988) New institutional spaces: flexible production organization and regional development in North American and Western Europe. Pion, LondonGoogle Scholar
  76. Simmie J (ed) (1997) Network and learning regions. Jessica Kingsley, LondonGoogle Scholar
  77. Smilor RW, Wakelin M (1990) Smart infrastructure and economic development: the role of technology and global networks. In: Kozmetzky G, Smilor RW (eds) The technopolis phenomenon. IC2 Institute, University of Texas, Austin, pp 53–75Google Scholar
  78. Shyy T-K, Song C, Stimson RJ, Stough RR (2009) Differentials in endogenous regional employment growth in U.S. metropolitan areas: the explanatory role of entrepreneurship and other leadership and institutional factors. In: Bernhard I (ed) The geography of innovation and entrepreneurship. Revised papers presented at the 12th Uddevalla symposium, Baari, Italy, 11–13 June 2009, Research reports 2009: 02, University West, Trollhattan, Sweden, pp 921–950Google Scholar
  79. Stimson RJ, Robson A, Shyy T-K (2009a) Measuring regional endogenous growth, Ch. 18. In: Capello R, Nijkamp PJ (eds) Handbook of regional growth and development theories. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, pp 354–372Google Scholar
  80. Stimson RJ, Robson A, Shyy T-K (2009b) Modelling regional endogenous growth: an application to the non-metropolitan regions of Australia. Ann Reg Sci 43:379–398CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  81. Stimson RJ, Rohde D, Shyy T-K, Mitchell W (2010) Using functional economic regions to model aspects of regional performance in Australia. Paper delivered to the Tinbergen Institute International Workshop 2010, modelling innovation, entrepreneurship and regional development, Amsterdam, 17–18 MayGoogle Scholar
  82. Stimson RJ, Stough RR, Salazar M (2005) Leadership and institutional factors in endogenous regional economic development. Investig Reg 7:23–52Google Scholar
  83. Stimson RJ, Stough RR (2009a) Regional economic development: methodology and analysis. In: Rowe JE (ed) Theories of local economic development: linking theory to practice. Ashgate, Farnham, pp 169–192Google Scholar
  84. Stimson RJ, Stough RR (2009b) Leadership, institutions and regional endogenous development. Edward Elgar, CheltenhamCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  85. Stimson RJ, Stough RR, Nijkamp P (eds) (2011) Endogenous regional development: perspectives, measurement and empirical investigation. Edward Elgar, CheltenhamGoogle Scholar
  86. Stimson R, Stough R, Roberts B (2006) Regional economic development: analysis and planning strategy. Springer, BerlinGoogle Scholar
  87. Taylor PJ, Catalano G, Gane N (2002) A geography of global change: services and cities 2000–01, GaWC Research Bulletin, Globalisation and World Cities Study Group and Network, 77, pp. 1–9.Google Scholar
  88. Thomas MD (1975) Growth pole theory, technological change and regional economic growth. Pap Reg Sci Assoc 34:3–25CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  89. Vasquez-Barquero BA (2002) Endogenous development: networking, innovation, institutions and cities. Routledge, LondonCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  90. Ward JH (1963) Hierarchical grouping to optimize an objective function. J Am Stat Assoc 58:236–244CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg 2014

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.Business SchoolUniversidad Adolfo IbáñezViña del MarChile
  2. 2.Australian Urban Research Infrastructure Network, Faculty of Architecture, Building and PlanningUniversity of MelbourneParkvilleAustralia
  3. 3.School of Public PolicyGeorge Mason UniversityFairfaxUSA

Personalised recommendations