Challenges to the Standard Euclidean Spatial Model

Abstract

Spatial models of political competition over multiple issues typically assume that agents’ preferences are represented by utility functions that are decreasing in the Euclidean distance to the agent’s ideal point in a multidimensional policy space. I describe theoretical and empirical results that challenge the assumption that quasiconcave, differentiable or separable utility functions, and in particular linear, quadratic or exponential Euclidean functions, adequately represent multidimensional preferences, and I propose solutions to address each of these challenges.

References

  1. Arabie P (1991) Was Euclid and unnecessarily sophisticated psychologist? Psychometrika 56(4):567–587 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Ashworth S, Bueno de Mesquita E (2009) Elections with platform and valence competition. Games Econ Behav 67(1):191–216 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. Azrieli Y (2011) Axioms for Euclidean preferences with a valence dimension. J Math Econ 47(4–5):545–553 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Banks JS, Duggan J (2008) A dynamic model of democratic elections in multidimensional policy spaces. Q J Polit Sci 3:269–299 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Berinsky AJ, Lewis JB (2007) An estimate of risk aversion in the U.S. electorate. Q J Polit Sci 2:139–154 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Black D (1948) On the rationale of group decision-making. J Polit Econ 56(1):23–34 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. Black D (1958) The theory of committees and elections. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge Google Scholar
  8. Bogomolnaia A, Laslier J-F (2007) Euclidean preferences. J Math Econ 43:87–98 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. Calvert R (1985) Robustness of the multidimensional voting model: candidate motivations, uncertainty and convergence. Am J Polit Sci 29:69–95 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Calvo E, Hellwig T, Chang K (2012) The eye of the beholder: ideological lensing, information effects, and the vote. In: Fundacion Juan March conference on contemporary applications of the spatial model Google Scholar
  11. Clinton JD, Jackman SD, Rivers D (2004) The statistical analysis of roll call data: a unified approach. Am Polit Sci Rev 98:355–370 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. D’Agostino M, Dardanoni V (2009) What’s so special about Euclidean distance? Soc Choice Welf 33(2):211–233 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Davis OA, DeGroot MH, Hinich MJ (1972) Social preference orderings and majority rule. Econometrica 40(1):147–157 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Degan A, Merlo A (2009) Do voters vote ideologically? J Econ Theory 144(5):1868–1894 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. Downs A (1957) An economic theory of political action in a democracy. J Polit Econ 65(2):135–150 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. Duggan J (2007) Equilibrium existence for zero-sum games and spatial models of elections. Games Econ Behav 60:52–74 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  17. Duggan J, Kalandrakis T (2012) Dynamic legislative policy bargaining. J Econ Theory Google Scholar
  18. Eguia JX (2009) Utility representations of risk neutral preferences in multiple dimensions. Q J Polit Sci 4(4):379–385 Google Scholar
  19. Eguia JX (2011a) On the spatial representation of preference profiles. Econ Theory (accepted for publication) Google Scholar
  20. Eguia JX (2011b) Foundations of spatial preferences. J Math Econ 47(2):200–205 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. Eguia JX (2012) A spatial theory of party formation. Econ Theory 49(3):549–570 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  22. Feddersen TJ (1992) A voting model implying Duverger’s law and positive turnout. Am J Polit Sci 36(4):938–962 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. Grynaviski JD, Corrigan BE (2006) Specification issues in proximity models of candidate evaluation (with issue importance). Polit Anal 14:393–420 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. Hotelling H (1929) Stability in competition. Econ J 39(153):41–57 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  25. Humphreys M, Laver M (2009) Spatial models, cognitive metrics and majority rule equilibria. Br J Polit Sci 40(1):11–30 Google Scholar
  26. Kamada Y, Kojima F (2010) Voter preferences, polarization and electoral policies. Working paper Google Scholar
  27. Kramer GH (1973) On a class of economic conditions for majority rule. Econometrica 41(2):285–297 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  28. Kramer GH (1977) A dynamical model of political equilibrium. J Econ Theory 16(2):310–334 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  29. Krasa S, Polborn M (2010) Competition between specialized candidates. Am Polit Sci Rev 104(4):745–765 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  30. Krasa S, Polborn M (2012) Political competition between differentiated candidates. Games Econ Behav 76(1):249–271 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  31. Lacy D (2001a) A theory of nonseparable preferences in survey responses. Am J Polit Sci 45(2):239–258 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  32. Lacy D (2001b) Nonseparable preferences, measurement error, and unstable survey responses. Polit Anal 9(2):1–21 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  33. Lacy D (2012) Nonseparable preferences, issue voting, and issue packaging in elections. In: Fundacion Juan March conference on contemporary applications of the spatial model Google Scholar
  34. McCarty N, Meirowitz A (2007) Political game theory. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  35. McKelvey RD (1976) Intransitivities in multidimensional voting models and some implications for agenda control. J Econ Theory 12:472–482 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  36. McKelvey RD (1979) General conditions for global intransitivities in formal voting models. Econometrica 47(5):1085–1112 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  37. McKelvey RD, Wendell RE (1976) Voting equilibria in multidimensional choice spaces. Math Oper Res 1(2):144–158 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  38. Miller G, Schofield N (2003) Activists and partisan realignment in the United States. Am Polit Sci Rev 97(2):245–260 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  39. Milyo J (2000a) A problem with Euclidean preferences in spatial models of politics. Econ Lett 66(2):179–182 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  40. Milyo J (2000b) Logical deficiencies in spatial models: a constructive critique. Public Choice 105(3–4):273–289 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  41. Minkowski H (1886) Geometrie der Zahlen. Teubner, Leipzig Google Scholar
  42. Osborne M (1995) Spatial models of political competition under plurality rule: a survey of some explanations of the number of candidates and the positions they take. Can J Econ 28(2):261–301 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  43. Patty JW, Snyder JM, Ting MM (2009) Two’s company, three’s an equilibrium: strategic voting and multicandidate elections. Q J Polit Sci 4(3):251–278 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  44. Plott CR (1967) A notion of equilibrium and its possibility under majority rule. Am Econ Rev 57(4):331–347 Google Scholar
  45. Poole K, Rosenthal H (1985) A spatial model for roll call analysis. Am J Polit Sci 29:331–347 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  46. Poole KT, Rosenthal H (1997) Congress: a political-economic history of roll call voting. Oxford University Press, London Google Scholar
  47. Rae DW, Taylor M (1971) Decision rules and policy outcomes. Br J Polit Sci 1:71–90 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  48. Rivero G (2011) Integrality and separability in multidimensional voting models: ideology and nationalism in Spanish regional elections. Center for Advanced Study in the Social Sciences, Fundacion Juan March, 2011/265, December Google Scholar
  49. Schofield N (1978) Instability of simple dynamic games. Rev Econ Stud 40(3):575–594 Google Scholar
  50. Schofield N (2007a) Political equilibria with electoral uncertainty. Soc Choice Welf 28:461–490 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  51. Schofield N (2007b) The mean voter theorem: necessary and sufficient conditions for convergent equilibrium. Rev Econ Stud 74:965–980 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  52. Schofield N, Claassen C, Gallego M, Ozdemir U (2011) Empirical and formal models of the United States presidential elections in 2000 and 2004. In: Schofield N, Caballero G (eds) Political economy of institutions, democracy and voting. Springer, Heidelberg CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  53. Schofield N, Sened I (2006) Multiparty democracy. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  54. Serra G (2010) Polarization of what? A model of elections with endogenous valence. J Polit 72(2):426–437 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  55. Serra G (2012) Does charisma discourage experience? an election with two types of valence. ICOPEAI II conference paper Google Scholar
  56. Shepard RN (1987) Toward a universal law of generalization for psychological science. Science 237:1317–1323 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  57. Shepsle KA, Weingast BR (1981) Structure-induced equilibrium and legislative choice. Public Choice 37(3):503–519 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  58. Wendell RE, Thorson SJ (1974) Some generalizations of social decisions under majority rule. Econometrica 42:893–912 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  59. Westholm A (1997) Distance versus direction: the illusory defeat of the proximity theory of electoral choice. Am Polit Sci Rev 91(4):865–883 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  60. Wittman D (1977) Candidates with policy preferences: a dynamic model. J Econ Theory 14(1):180–189 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  61. Wittman D (1983) Candidate motivation: a synthesis of alternatives. Am Polit Sci Rev 77(1):142–157 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  62. Ye M, Li Q, Leiker KW (2011) Evaluating voter-candidate proximity in a non-Euclidean space. J Elect Public Opin Parties 4:497–521 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  63. Zakharov A (2009) A model of candidate location with endogenous valence. Public Choice 138:347–366 CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg 2013

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.Department of PoliticsNew York UniversityNew YorkUSA

Personalised recommendations