Skip to main content

The ECB’s Monetary Analysis Revisited

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
The European Central Bank at Ten

Abstract

Money plays an important role in the European Central Bank’s (ECB’s) monetary policy strategy. According to the ECB, monetary analysis (formerly known as the “monetary pillar”) helps to guide the policy-making process of the Governing Council by providing information on “medium to long-term trends in inflation, given the close relationship between money and prices over extended horizons” (ECB, 2003a, p. 79). It also serves as a communication device by stressing the ECB commitment to price stability. While a certain proximity to the monetary targeting framework of the German Bundesbank was intentional when the ECB announced its strategy, the ECB later made it clear that monetary analysis is neither its sole nor its most important guide to policy decisions. Today, the prime function of monetary analysis is to serve “as a means of cross-checking, from a medium to long-term perspective, the short to medium-term indications coming from economic analysis” (ECB, 2003a, p. 87), which is a broad-based analysis of price developments in the short to medium run based on non-monetary indicators. Still, the continued explicit reliance on money to guide monetary policy is a distinguishing feature of the ECB’s framework compared to that of other central banks.

The views expressed herein are those of the authors and should not be attributed to the IMF, its Executive Board, or its management.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    See Beyer and Reichlin (2008).

  2. 2.

    This exchange was reflected in a speech by Banque de France Governor Christian Noyer (2007), who suggested excluding from the ECB’s money growth figures growth stemming from money holding by private equity or investment funds. ECB Vice-President Lucas Papademos, also in a public appearance, was later reported to refute the idea, however, pointing to the role of the broader aggregate as an inflation indicator (Reuters, 2007). Bloomberg (2007) reported around the same time that ECB President Claude Trichet and German Bundesbank Governor Axel Weber in public supported an important role for money in ECB monetary policy (see also Dow Jones, 2007).

  3. 3.

    According to the ECB (1999, p. 43), in addition to the guiding goal of price stability, the monetary strategy “imposes a clear structure on the policy-making process” and is a “vehicle for communicating with the public”. See also ECB (2004a). In what follows, we focus only on the two latter elements.

  4. 4.

    The notion of monetary analysis as a “cross check” of economic analysis also implies that both approaches apply to the same policy-relevant time horizon (see e.g., Jaeger, 2003).

  5. 5.

    The ECB is constantly working on improving its monetary analysis. For example, Papademos (2006, p. 4) points out that the ECB is carrying out research aimed at “…incorporating a richer financial sector into dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models, in order to study the role of financial variables in the conduct of monetary policy”. He goes on to note that (p. 5) “…the monetary analysis of the ECB has evolved over time and is fairly comprehensive, going beyond the standard assessment based on the quantity theory of money and the stability of money demand”. Beyond the improvements of the macroeconomic part of the monetary analysis, Papademos (2006, p. 6) also emphasis “the usefulness of monitoring and assessing monetary and credit developments…for the safeguarding of financial stability”.

  6. 6.

    More recently, Fatás, Mihov and Rose (2007) showed that empirically any (and not just monetary) nominal target that is systematically achieved by the central bank is associated with low inflation.

  7. 7.

    See also European Central Bank (2003a, p. 79) and Issing, Angeloni, Gaspar, Klöckers, Masuch, Nicoletti-Altimari, Rostagno, and Smets (2003).

  8. 8.

    Unless otherwise stated, all variables in Sects. 3.3.1 and 3.3.2 are defined as (log) deviations from the steady state marked by a “^”.

  9. 9.

    Equilibrium determinacy is discussed, for instance, in Woodford (2003). Also see Sect. 3.3.2. Note that, except for the notation in deviations from the steady state, Eq. 3.3 is similar to a forward-looking Taylor rule with inertia, where the central bank reacts to deviations of inflation from its inflation target (assumed to be identical with the steady state) and the output gap from its steady state (assumed to compatible with the inflation target).

  10. 10.

    Fischer, Lenza, Pill and Reichlin (2008) stress that the ECB’s Quarterly Monetary Assessment is mostly (albeit not exclusively) targeted at medium- to long-term inflation forecasting. See also the background study by Masuch, Nicoletti, Altimari, Rostagno and Pill (2003).

  11. 11.

    As far as the aggregate implications are concerned, the non-separability argument is conceptually close the idea that real monetary balances have a direct demand effect in the tradition of Pigou and Patinkin. Ireland (2001) develops a real balance effect in a cash-in-advance DSGE framework under separable utility. However, the real balance effect has been met with skepticism, owing, in part, to the dominance of non-money holdings in private wealth and the fact that outside money (i.e. currency in circulation) is only a small fraction of monetary aggregates (see Nelson, 2003; Brand, Reimers and Seitz, 2003). The Bundesbank (2005) summarizes the evidence on the real balance model as weak at best for the US, the UK, and the euro area as a whole.

  12. 12.

    Note that—assuming a standard household utility function u(.) with u c , u m > 0, u cc , u mm < 0, and u cm > 0—the direct and indirect impact of contemporaneous money on inflation move into opposite directions, with the overall impact being a question of the underlying parameters and, thus, ultimately an empirical matter.

  13. 13.

    A variant of the above model introduces, in addition, non-separability across period—that is, habit persistence in consumption. Andrés, López-Salido and Nelson (2007) show that this adds inertia to output and inflation, and money demand conveys forward-looking information on output similar to what we discuss in Sect. 3.4 around Eq. 3.8.

  14. 14.

    The results of Kremer et al. (2003) are more pronounced in some time samples than others. Also note that their solution technique deviates from Ireland (2004) and Andrés et al. (2006) in that it does not force a non-explosive solution in the Taylor-type rule.

  15. 15.

    See also Brand et al. (2003). Masuch et al. (2003) discuss empirical evidence supporting the view that the money stock serves as a proxy for a spectrum of interest rates. As Nelson (2002) shows, the adjustment-cost approach discussed below can be interpreted as a simple formalization of this idea within a DSGE model.

  16. 16.

    Svensson (2003b, p. 1070), too, calls the idea of money as an indicator variable “the potentially most useful role for money in monetary policy analysis”. See also Smets (2003).

  17. 17.

    Stepping outside the DSGE approach, he looks at a simple economy with a Phillips curve and a standard money demand function. If the productivity increase was fully accommodated by output growth, inflation would remain constant but the money stock would (still) increase.

  18. 18.

    Fischer et al. (2008) also document at some length how the increasing importance of portfolio-related changes for the development of monetary aggregates from the year 2001 onward have reduced the usefulness of mechanical money demand functions for the ECB’s Quarterly Monetary Assessment.

  19. 19.

    Also see Orphanides (2003). The concept of potential output in current New Keynesian DSGE models is not necessarily identical with the long-run trend of output. See, for example, Clarida et al. (1999) and Woodford (2003) for a discussion.

  20. 20.

    Given potential output, the link to inflation would be provided by a dynamic AS-equation such as Eq. 3.1. The fact that monetary policy involves complex transmission processes, including port-folio rebalancing, has also recently been stressed by Goodfriend (2000).

  21. 21.

    Note that a simple cash-in-advance constraint of the form M t−1 /P t−1  > Y t (with P indicating the price level and M the nominal level of the money stock) would, in principle, also create forward-looking behavior of households or investors. The standard assumption is M t /P t  > Y t , which is mimicked by money-in-utility frameworks where the contemporaneous money stock enters the utility function.

  22. 22.

    Habit persistence in consumption would further enrich the dynamics of Eq. 3.8. As Nelson (2002) notes, one interpretation of the equation is that it illustrates the dependence of money demand on long-run asset prices (i.e. interest rates) in the spirit of Meltzer’s (2001) argument discussed earlier. See Coenen et al. (2005) for a related discussion.

  23. 23.

    In general, this will also hold for a policy rule conditioning the interest rate on expected inflation. Assume, for instance, the central bank does not observe the output gap. Based on Eq. 3.5, neither current inflation nor expected inflation will be perfectly correlated with the output gap. Thus money is always likely to add to the central bank’s information set because, just like the output gap itself, it depends on the future time path of interest rates (see also Nelson, 2002).

  24. 24.

    In a broadly related result, Leeper and Roush (2003) find that adding a monetary argument to the interest rates equation improves the fit of empirical impulse responses to monetary shocks for US data (see, e.g., Leeper, Sims and Zah, 1996 and Christiano, Eichenbaum and Evans, 1998 for earlier work). Smets (2003) interprets this as supporting the informational content of money.

  25. 25.

    Also see, for instance, recent contributions from Christiano and Rostagno (2001), Christiano et al. (2005), and Goodfriend and McCallum (2007).

  26. 26.

    The same holds for the reduction in the stringency of reserve requirements. For the US case, Loutskina and Strahan (2008) show empirically how financial innovation, in particular securitization, has reduced the impact of lending conditions set by monetary policy on credit supply.

  27. 27.

    See Bernanke (2007). Making a related point, Van den Heuvel (2007) models bank lending in the presence of capital adequacy regulations but without reserve requirements. The results imply lending will depend, among other things, on banks’ financial structure and interest rates.

  28. 28.

    On the financial accelerator, Greiber and Setzer (2007) and Bundesbank (2005) report that expansionary monetary conditions have positive feedback effects on housing prices, which Greiber and Setzer (2007, p. 2) take to imply that “a stronger case can be made for … the indicator properties of money.” See, however, the discussion above.

  29. 29.

    McCallum (2001), von Hagen (2004), and Masuch et al. (2003), among others, make similar points.

  30. 30.

    As Woodford (2003) shows, the determinacy conditions may involve both lower- and upper-bounds for the reaction to state variables if the Taylor-type rule is forward-looking and the κ ≥ 0.

  31. 31.

    See also Christiano and Rostagno (2001), Benhabib, Schmitt-Grohe and Uribe (2001a), and Carlstrom and Fuerst (2002). As Christiano et al. (2008) explain, balance-sheet effects along the lines previously discussed could also be part of the supply-side impact of interest rates.

  32. 32.

    Galí et al. (2004, p.31) stress that rules that bind the central bank’s nominal policy rate to endogenous variables, including real variables, can be interpreted as a commitment to as money supply target—albeit one that excludes money: “A commitment to a money-supply target implies a commitment to raise nominal interest rates at a certain rate in response to increases in the general level of prices above that characteristic for the optimal equilibrium, and similarly to raise interest rates in response to increases in real activity; otherwise, the central bank would be accommodating the increased money demand that would result from increases in either prices or real activity”.

  33. 33.

    Similar conclusions seem to hold for the related debate on multiple global equilibria. As, for instance, Benhabib et al. (2001a, b) demonstrate, local determinacy may go hand-in-hand with global indeterminacy—for instance, in the case of a self-fulfilling deflationary trap where the nominal interest rate drops to its zero lower bound. However, Woodford (2003) argues that some plausible learning processes can ensure that the forces anchoring the locally stable equilibrium also anchor the global equilibrium if shocks to expectations are not too large. Moreover, the problem of globally indeterminate equilibria is not confined to Taylor-type rules and can also occur under monetary strategies based on money targeting.

  34. 34.

    See, among others, Hallman, Porter and Small (1991), Tödter and Reimers (1997), Neumann (1997), Orphanides and Porter (2000), and Masuch, Pill and Willeke (2001).

  35. 35.

    Unless otherwise stated, all variables in Sect. 3.3 are defined as (log) levels.

  36. 36.

    Equation 3.9 nests a number of P* approaches. Hallman et al. (1991), for instance, assume α = 1, which seems to be in line with Reynard’s (2007) empirical observation that the price gap influences inflation with considerable lags and some persistence.

  37. 37.

    As discussed, the other channel works through the demand (or Euler) equation (Eq. 3.6), and both interact in the general equilibrium. In addition, the parameters in Eq. 3.5 are structural in nature.

  38. 38.

    See Benati (2005), Gerlach and Svensson (2003), Jaeger (2003), Neumann and Greiber (2004), Christiano and Fitzgerald (2003), Backhus and Kehoe (1992), or Lucas (1980) for other (also mostly empirical) work in the same direction.

  39. 39.

    The difference to the P* model is less pronounced in Gerlach and Svensson’s (2003) specification of the two-pillar Phillips curve which is based on the real money gap instead of long-run excess money growth.

  40. 40.

    See Bordes and Clerc (2007) for a similar discussion of the underpinnings of Eq. 3.13. Interestingly, according to Gerlach (2004), the ECB (2001b) in an early description of its policy framework explicitly allowed for the possibility of a direct impact of money on inflation expectations—a statement that was removed from later editions of the book (ECB, 2004a, b).

  41. 41.

    Compare Nelson (2007) and Beck and Wieland (2007b), who discuss the two-pillar Phillips curve but ultimately reject it as a-theoretical. Ireland (2004), too, states that a thorough analysis of the role of real balances in the macro economy may require more than adding money to the Phillips curve.

  42. 42.

    Yet another strand of research, as e.g. in Stavrev (2006) and Hofmann (2008), combines a variety of approaches for inflation forecasting. While perhaps helpful as a forecasting tool, this approach provides little guidance for the question at hand.

  43. 43.

    All models are initially estimated over the same training period, 1993Q1–1999Q4, and their inflation forecasting performance is assessed for the period 2000Q1–2007Q2. See Berger and Stavrev (2008).

  44. 44.

    The adjustment cost results are particularly interesting because Berger and Stavrev (2008) condition the central bank’s interest rate function on model-consistent expected inflation. The improvement in forecasting accuracy from incorporating monetary factors in the interest rate rule suggests that money supplies additional information. As discussed in Sect. 3.3.2, one reason could be that because of informational frictions the central bank does not fully observe the state of the economy reflected, in part, in monetary developments.

  45. 45.

    Money affects inflation mainly through improving the empirical specification of the aggregate demand and aggregate supply equations, while the effects from the fact that monetary policy reacts to money balances in the generalized models (see Sect. 3.3.2) is small.

  46. 46.

    One possible explanation for the relatively weak performance of the money-enhanced partial equilibrium may be their particular sensitivity to money demand instability. Fischer et al. (2008) also note that, from the perspective of forecasting practitioners, simple bivariate models foregoing an explicit money demand specification are dominating other approaches.

  47. 47.

    For instance, Bruggeman, Donato and Warne (2003) find long-run euro area money demand consistently related to real GDP. Dreger and Wolters (2006) also argue that standard money demand functions are well capable of explaining the recent surge in euro area liquidity provided that the short-run homogeneity restriction on money and prices is dropped. See, among others, the surveys by Calza and Sousa (2003), Golinelli and Pastorello (2002), and Ericsson (1998).

  48. 48.

    See, for example, the discussion in Friedman and Kuttner (1996) and Kahn and Benolkin (2007).

  49. 49.

    The demand for cash also depends on the size of an economy’s informal sector and its use abroad.

  50. 50.

    For instance, according to Friedman and Kuttner (1996), the Federal Reserve targeted money mainly during 1975–1982, in the sense that it varied either the federal funds rate or non-borrowed reserves (whichever, was the policy instrument at the time) in response to observed fluctuations or either M1 or M2 that departed from the corresponding stated targets.

  51. 51.

    Some argue that money remains important for central banks to control the overnight interbank interest rate, but Woodford (2003) maintains that the achievement of the central bank’s interest target does not require any quantity adjustments through open-market operations in response to deviations of the market rate from the target rate.

  52. 52.

    According to ECB staff, augmenting money demand equations after they have proven unstable over time should be seen as providing ex post support for the judgmental adjustment of M3 rather than a plausible alternative framework for making that judgmental assessment in real time (Fischer et al., 2008).

  53. 53.

    See, the ECB’s Monetary Bulletins from October 2004 and July 2007.

  54. 54.

    See, for example, ECB Monthly Bulletins May 2003, October 2004, and January 2005.

  55. 55.

    Berger and Harjes (2009) find a potential link between global liquidity, primarily determined by US liquidity, and euro area inflation.

  56. 56.

    See ECB (2004b), p.49.

  57. 57.

    See Faruqee (2005) for a more formal treatment of the question of structural breaks in euro area velocity.

  58. 58.

    Securitization may broadly be defined as the process of converting a pool of designated financial assets into tradable securities backed by cash flows of the assets and their underlying collateral (see European Securitization Forum, 1999; ECB, 2008).

  59. 59.

    It is important to reiterate that money does not affect prices directly according the bank lending channel but through its impact on demand and output (see Bernanke and Gertler, 1995).

  60. 60.

    ECB (2008, p. 91) and Altunbas et al. (2007). Gross euro area securitization issuance of about euro 300 billion amounts to roughly 2 percentage points but not all of this was passed on by banks via “true sales”, or sold on to the market at all.

  61. 61.

    See, among others, Kydland and Prescott (1977) and Fudenberg and Maskin (1986) for important contributions to the literature on reputation and the so-called inflation bias. Clarida et al. (1999), and Woodford (2003) discuss the related problem of a stabilization bias.

  62. 62.

    It is interesting to note that the Bundesbank was in a similar situation at the onset of the European Monetary System (EMS) in 1979, when several of members of its council were initially directly in favor of abandoning monetary targeting strategy. However, as von Hagen (1999) writes, later on they acknowledged the importance of “the high reputation the strategy had gained the Bank abroad” and supported the strategy, recognizing that its abandoning “the time when the new EMS was beginning to operate would create the impression that the Bundesbank was giving up on its efforts to maintain price stability and would fuel inflation expectations”.

  63. 63.

    See Issing (2006, p. 2) and Jaeger (2003). A certain overplaying of the importance of monetary targeting in actual decision-making was also part of the Bundesbank’s monetary strategy (see, for instance, Posen, 2000).

  64. 64.

    Their basic setup is a regression of the change in the Euribor rate on the post-meeting policy rate surprise (i.e., the difference between the actual post-meeting policy rate and the expected rate) and a communication indicator based on Berger et al. (2010).

  65. 65.

    In a related result, Bulíř, Čihák and Šmídková (2008) report that there are indications that information on the ECB’s policy inclination based on the “monetary pillar” is frequently out of sync with other signals send by the ECB, including the staff’s inflation forecast, press releases, or monthly bulletins.

References

  • Alesina, A., Blanchard, O., Galí, J., Giavazzi, F., & Uhlig, H. (2001a). Defining a macroeconomic framework for the euro area. Monitoring the European Central Bank No. 3. London: CEPR.

    Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, A., Blanchard, O., Galí, J., Giavazzi, F., & Uhlig, H. (2001b). MECB update. London: CEPR.

    Google Scholar 

  • Altunbas, Y., Gambacorta, L., & Marques, D. (2007). Securitization and the bank lending channel. ECB Working Paper No. 838.

    Google Scholar 

  • Andrés, J., López-Salido, D., & Nelson, E. (2007). Money and the natural rate of interest: structural estimates for the UK, the US and the euro area. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series No. 2007–05A.

    Google Scholar 

  • Andrés, J., López-Salido, D., & Vallés, J. (2006). Money in an estimated business cycle model of the euro area. The Economic Journal, 116, 457–477.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Angeloni, I., Kashyap, A., Mojon, B., & Terlizzese, D. (2002). Monetary transmission in the euro area: where do we stand? ECB Working Paper No. 114.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aoki, K. (2006). Optimal commitment policy under noisy information. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 30(1), 81–109.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ashley, R., Granger, C. W. J., & Schmalensee, R. (1980). Advertising and aggregate consumption: an analysis of causality. Econometrica, 48, 1149–1167.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Assenmacher-Wesche, K., & Gerlach, S. (2006a). Interpreting euro area inflation at high and low frequencies. BIS Working Paper No. 195.

    Google Scholar 

  • Assenmacher-Wesche, K., & Gerlach, S. (2006b). Understanding the link between money growth and inflation in the euro area. mimeo.

    Google Scholar 

  • Assenmacher-Wesche, K., Gerlach, S., & Sekine, T. (2007). Monetary factors and inflation in Japan. mimeo.

    Google Scholar 

  • Backhus, D., & Kehoe, P. (1992). International evidence of the historical properties of business cycles. American Economic Review, 82(4), 864–888.

    Google Scholar 

  • Beck, G., & Wieland, V. (2007a). Money in monetary policy design under uncertainty: a formal characterization of ECB-style cross-checking. Journal of the European Economic Association, 5(2–3), 524–533.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beck, G., & Wieland, V. (2007b). Money in monetary policy design under uncertainty: the two-pillar Phillips curve versus ECB-style cross-checking. mimeo.

    Google Scholar 

  • Beechey, M. J., Johannsen, B. K., & Levin, A. T. (2008). Are long-run inflation expectations anchored more firmly in the euro area than in the United States? Finance and Economics Discussion Series, Federal Reserve Board, Washington, DC.

    Google Scholar 

  • Benati, L. (2005). Long-run evidence on money growth and inflation. Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin, Autumn, 349–355.

    Google Scholar 

  • Benhabib, J., Schmitt-Grohe, S., & Uribe, M. (2001a). Monetary policy and multiple equilibria. American Economic Review, 91(1), 167–186.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benhabib, J., Schmitt-Grohe, S., & Uribe, M. (2001b). The perils of Taylor rules. Journal of Economic Theory, 96(1), 40–69.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berger, H., De Haan, J., & Sturm, J.-E. (2010). Does money matter in the ECB strategy? New evidence based on ECB communication. International Journal of Finance and Economics, forthcoming.

    Google Scholar 

  • Berger, H., & Harjes, T. (2009). Does global liquidity matter for monetary policy in the euro area? International Finance, 12(1), 33–55.

    Google Scholar 

  • Berger, H., & Österholm, P. (2008a). Does money growth granger-cause inflation in the euro area? Evidence from out-of-sample forecasts using Bayesian VARs. Economic Record, forthcoming.

    Google Scholar 

  • Berger, H., & Österholm, P. (2008b). Does money matter for U.S. inflation? Evidence from Bayesian VARs. IMF Working Paper No. 08/76.

    Google Scholar 

  • Berger, H., & Stavrev, E. (2008). The information content of money in forecasting euro area inflation. IMF Working Paper No. 08/166.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bernanke, B. (2007). The financial accelerator and the credit channel, speech at the credit channel of monetary policy in the twenty-first century conference. Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta, June 15. Available at: http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/bernanke20070615a.htm.

  • Bernanke, B., & Blinder, A. (1988). Credit, money, and aggregate demand. American Economic Review, 78, 435–439.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bernanke, B., & Gertler, M. (1995). Inside the black box: the credit channel of monetary policy transmission. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 9(4), 27–48.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernanke, B., Gertler, M., & Gilchrist, S. (1996). The financial accelerator in a quantitative business cycle framework. Review of Economics and Statistics, 78(1), 1–15.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernanke, B., Laubach, T., Mishkin, F. S., & Posen, A. S. (1999). Inflation targeting: lessons from the international experience. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Beyer, A., & Reichlin, L. (2008). The role of money—money and monetary policy in the twenty-first century. In: A. Beyer, L. Reichlin (Eds.), Proceedings of the 4th ECB central banking conference, 9–10 November 2006. Frankfurt: ECB.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bini-Smaghi, L., & Gros, D. (2000). Open issues in European central banking. London: Macmillan Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Bloomberg (2007). Trichet, Noyer split over money supply clouds ECB rate outlook. Online News Report, 4 June. Available at: http://www.bloomberg.com/apps/news?pid=20601109&sid=a.JaL_23jXV0&refer=home#.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boone, L., Mikol, F., & van den Noord, P. (2004). Wealth effects on money demand in EMU: econometric evidence. OECD Economics Department Working Paper No. 411.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bordes, C., & Clerc, L. (2007). Price stability and the ECB’s monetary policy strategy. Journal of Economic Surveys, 21(2), 268–325.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bordes, C., Clerc, L., & Marimoutou, V. (2007). Is there a structural break in equilibrium velocity in the euro area. Notes D’Études Et De Recherche, NER–E165.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brand, C., Reimers, H., & Seitz, F. (2003). Forecasting real GDP: what role for narrow money? In O. Issing (Ed.), Background studies for the ECB’s evaluation of its monetary policy strategy (pp. 302–333). Frankfurt: European Central Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bruggeman, A., Donato, P., & Warne, A. (2003). Is the demand for euro area M3 stable? In O. Issing (Ed.), Background studies for the ECB’s evaluation of its monetary policy strategy (pp. 246–300). Frankfurt: European Central Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bulíř, A., Čihák, M., & Šmídková, K. (2008). Writing clearly: ECB’s monetary policy communication. IMF Working Paper No. 08/252.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bundesbank. (2005). The relationship between money and prices. Monthly report, 13–24 Jan 2005. Deutsche: Bundesbank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Calza, A., Gerdesmeier, D., & Levy, J. (2001). Euro area money demand: measuring the opportunity cost appropriately. IMF Working Paper No. 179/01.

    Google Scholar 

  • Calza, A., & Sousa, J. (2003). Why has broad money demand been more stable in the euro area than in other economies? A literature review. In O. Issing (Ed.), Background studies for the ECB’s evaluation of its monetary policy strategy (pp. 229–243). Frankfurt: European Central Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carlstrom, C., & Fuerst, T. (2002). Taylor rules in a model that satisfies the natural-rate hypothesis. American Economic Review, 92(2), 79–84.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Christiano, L., Eichenbaum, M., & Evans, C. (1998). Monetary policy shocks: what have we learned and to what end? In J. Taylor, M. Woodford (Eds.), Handbook of macroeconomics (pp. 65–148), Vol. 1. Amsterdam: Elsevier.

    Google Scholar 

  • Christiano, L., Eichenbaum, M., & Evans, C. (2005). Nominal rigidities and the dynamic effects of a shock to monetary policy. Journal of Political Economy, 113(1), 1–45.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Christiano, L., & Fitzgerald, T. (2003). Inflation and monetary policy in the 20th century. Economic perspectives (Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago) 1Q, 21–45.

    Google Scholar 

  • Christiano, L., Motto, R., & Rostagno, M. (2008). Two reasons why money and credit may be useful in monetary policy. In: A. Beyer, L. Reichlin (Eds.), The role of money—money and monetary policy in the twenty-first century. Proceedings of the 4th ECB central banking conference (pp. 28–55), 9–10 November 2006. Frankfurt: ECB.

    Google Scholar 

  • Christiano, L., & Rostagno, M. (2001). Money growth monitoring and the Taylor rule. NBER Working Paper No. 8539.

    Google Scholar 

  • Clarida, R., Galí, J., & Gertler, M. (1999). The science of monetary policy: a New Keynesian perspective. Journal of Economic Literature, 37(4), 1661–1707.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coenen, G., Levin, A., & Wieland, V. (2005). Data uncertainty and the role of money as an informational variable for monetary policy. European Economic Review, 49(4), 975–1006.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coffinet, J., & Gouteron, S. (2007). Euro area market reactions to the monetary developments press release. ECB Working Paper No. 792.

    Google Scholar 

  • Conrad, C., & Lamla, M. J. (2007). The high-frequency response of the EUR-US dollar exchange rate to ECB monetary policy announcements. KOF (Swiss Economic Institute) Working Paper No. 07-174.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cukierman, A. (2001). Accountability, credibility, transparency, and stabilization in the eurosystem. In C. Wyplosz (Ed.), The impact of EMU on Europe and the developing countries (pp. 40–75). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • D’Agostino, A., Giannone, D., & Surico, P. (2006). (Un)Predictability and macroeconomic stability. ECB Working Paper No. 605.

    Google Scholar 

  • De Grauwe, P., & Polan, M. (2005). Is inflation always and everywhere a monetary phenomenon? Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 107(2), 239–59.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Haan, J., Eijffinger, S. C. W., & Waller, S. (2005). The European Central Bank credibility, transparency, and centralization. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Diamond, D., & Rajan, R. (2001). Liquidity risk, liquidity creation, and financial fragility: a theory of banking. Journal of Political Economy, 109(2), 287–327.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diamond, D., & Rajan, R. (2006). Money in a theory of banking. American Economic Review, 96(1), 30–53.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dotsey, M., & Hornstein, A. (2003). Should monetary policy makers look at money? Journal of Monetary Economics, 50(3), 547–579.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dow, J. (2007). Weber warnt vor Aufgabe der monetären Säule in EZB-Strategie. Online News Report, 29 May. Available at: http://www.djnewswires.de/news.php?id=11134.

  • Dreger, C., & Wolters, J. (2006). Investigating M3 money demand in the euro area—new evidence based on standard models. DIW Berlin Discussion Papers No. 561.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ehrmann, M., Gambacorta, L., Martinez-Pages, J., Sevestre, P., & Worms, A. (2003). Financial systems and the role of banks in monetary policy transmission in the euro area. In I. Angeloni, A. Kashyap, B. Mojon (Eds.), Monetary policy transmission in the euro area: a study by the eurosystem monetary transmission network (pp. 235–269). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ericsson, N. (1998). Empirical modeling of money demand. Empirical Economics, 23(3), 295–315.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • European Central Bank. (1998). A stability-oriented monetary policy strategy for the ESCB. Press release, 13 October 1998. Available at: http://www.ecb.int/press/pr/date/1998/html/pr981013_1.en.html.

  • European Central Bank. (1999). The stability-oriented monetary policy strategy of the eurosystem. Monthly Bulletin, January, 39–50.

    Google Scholar 

  • European Central Bank. (2001). The monetary policy of the ECB. ECB: Frankfurt.

    Google Scholar 

  • European Central Bank. (2003a). The outcome of the ECB’s evaluation of its monetary policy strategy. Monthly Bulletin, June, 79–90.

    Google Scholar 

  • European Central Bank. (2003b). The ECB’s monetary policy strategy. Press release, 8 May 2003. Available at: http://www.ecb.int/press/pr/date/2003/html/pr030508_2.en.html#.

  • European Central Bank (2004a). The monetary policy of the ECB, 2nd edn. ECB: Frankfurt

    Google Scholar 

  • European Central Bank. (2004b). Monetary analysis in real time. Monthly Bulletin, February, 43–66.

    Google Scholar 

  • European Central Bank. (2008). Securitisation in the euro area. Monthly Bulletin, February, 81–94.

    Google Scholar 

  • European Securitization Forum. (1999). european securitization: a resource guide. Available at: http://www.europeansecuritisation.com/esfPubs.shtml.

  • Faruqee, H. (2005). Declining money velocity in the euro area: implications for the ECB’s monetary analysis (pp. 32–61). IMF Country Report No. 05/266.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fatás, A., Mihov, I., & Rose, A. (2007). Quantitative goals for monetary policy. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 39(5), 1163–1176.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ferrero, G., Nobili, A., & Passiglia, P. (2007). The sector distribution of money supply in the euro area. Banca D’Italia, Temi Di Discussione Del Servizio Studi No. 627.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fischer, B., Lenza, M., Pill, H., & Reichlin, L. (2008). Money and monetary policy: the ECB experience 1999–2006. In A. Beyer, L. Reichlin (Eds.), The role of money—money and monetary policy in the twenty-first century. Proceedings of the 4th ECB central banking conference (pp. 102–175), 9–10 November 2006, ECB: Frankfurt.

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, B. M., & Kuttner, K. N. (1996). A price target for U.S. monetary policy? Lessons from the experience with money growth targets. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1:77–146.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fudenberg, D., & Maskin, E. (1986). Folk theorems for repeated games with discounting or incomplete information. Econometrica, 54(3), 533–54.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fuhrer, J. (2000). Habit formation in consumption and its implications for monetary—policy models. American Economic Review, 90(3), 367–90.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Galí, J. (2008). Comment. In: A. Beyer, L. Reichlin (Eds.), The role of money—money and monetary policy in the twenty-first century. Proceedings of the 4th ECB central banking conference (pp. 182–189), 9–10 November 2006. ECB: Frankfurt.

    Google Scholar 

  • Galí, J., Gerlach, S., Rotemberg, J., Uhlig, H., & Woodford, M. (2004). The monetary policy strategy of the ECB reconsidered. Monitoring the European Central Bank No. 5. CEPR: London.

    Google Scholar 

  • Galí, J., & Gertler, M. (2007). Macroeconomic modeling for monetary policy evaluation. Universitat Pompeu Fabra Department of Economics and Business Working Papers No. 1039.

    Google Scholar 

  • Geraats, P., Giavazzi, F., & Wyplosz, C. (2008). Transparency and governance. Monitoring the European Central Bank No. 6. CEPR: London.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gerlach, S. (2004). The two pillars of the European Central Bank, Economic Policy, 40, October, 389–439.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gerlach, S., & Svensson, L. (2003). Money and inflation in the euro area: a case for monetary indicators? Journal of Monetary Economics, 50(8), 1649–1672.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Golinelli, R., & Pastorello, S. (2002). Modeling the demand for M3 in the euro area. European Journal of Finance, 8(4), 371–401.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goodfriend, M. (2000). Overcoming the zero bound on interest rate policy. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 32(4), 1007–1035.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goodfriend, M., & McCallum, B. (2007). Banking and interest rates in monetary policy analysis: a quantitative exploration. Journal of Monetary Economics, 54(5), 1480–1507.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greiber, C., & Lemke, W. (2005). Money demand and macroeconomic uncertainty. Deutsche Bundesbank Discussion Paper No. 26/2005.

    Google Scholar 

  • Greiber, C., & Setzer, R. (2007). Money and housing—evidence for the euro area and the US. Deutsche Bundesbank Discussion Paper No. 12/2007.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hallman, J., Porter, R., & Small, D. (1991). Is the price level tied to the M2 monetary aggregate in the long run? The American Economic Review, 81(4), 841–58.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hofmann, B. (2008). Do monetary indicators lead euro area inflation? ECB Working Paper No. 867.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ireland, P. (2001). The real balance effect. NBER Working Paper No. 8136.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ireland, P. (2004). Money’s role in the monetary business cycle. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 36(6), 969–983.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Issing, O. (2001). The euro area and the single monetary policy. Österreichische Nationalbank Working Paper No. 44.

    Google Scholar 

  • Issing, O. (2003). In I. Angeloni, V. Gaspar, H. Klöckers, K. Masuch, S. Nicoletti-Altimari, M. Rostagno, F. Smets (Eds.), Background studies for the ECB’s evaluation of its monetary policy strategy. ECB: Frankfurt.

    Google Scholar 

  • Issing, O. (2006). The ECB’s monetary policy strategy: why did we choose a two pillar approach? Available at: www.ecb.int/events/pdf/conferences/cbc4/Issing.pdf.

  • Issing, O., Gaspar, V., Angeloni, I., & Tristani, O. (2001). Monetary policy in the euro area, strategy and decision-making at the European Central Bank. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Jaeger, A. (2003). The ECB’s money pillar: an assessment. IMF Working Paper No. 03/82.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jones, B., & Stracca, L. (2006). Are money and consumption additively separable in the euro area? A non-parametric approach. ECB Working Paper No. 704.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kahn, G., & Benolkin, S. (2007). The role of money in monetary policy: why do the Fed and the ECB see it so differently? Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Economic Review, Third Quarter, 5–36.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kremer, J., Lombardo, G., & Werner, T. (2003). Money in a new-Keynesian model estimated with German data. Deutsche Bundesbank Discussion Paper No. 15/2003.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kydland, F., & Prescott, E. (1977). Rules rather than discretion: the inconsistency of optimal plans. Journal of Political Economy, 85(3), 473–91.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lamla, M., & Rupprecht, S. (2006). The impact of ECB communication on financial market expectations. KOF (Swiss Economic Institute) Working Paper No. 06–135.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leeper, E., & Roush, J. (2003). Putting “M” back in monetary policy. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 35(6), 1217–57.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leeper, E., Sims, C., & Zah, T. (1996). What does monetary policy do? Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2, 1–78.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Loutskina, E., & Strahan, P. (2008). Securitization and the declining impact of bank finance on loan supply: evidence from mortgage originators. mimeo.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lubik, T., & P. Surico (2006). The Lucas critique and the stability of empirical models. Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Working Paper No. 06–05.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lucas, R. (1980). Two illustrations of the quantity theory of money. American Economic Review, 70(5), 1005–1014.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lucas, R. (1986). Adaptive behavior and economic theory. The Journal of Business, 59(4), 401–426.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Masuch, K., Nicoletti, S., Altimari, S., Rostagno, M., & Pill, H. (2003). The role of money in monetary policymaking. In O. Issing (Ed.), Background studies for the ECB’s evaluation of its monetary policy strategy (pp. 187–228). Frankfurt: European Central Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Masuch, K., Pill, H., & Willeke, C. (2001). Framework and tools of monetary analysis. In H. Klöckers & C. Willeke (Eds.), Monetary analysis: tools and applications (pp. 117–144). Frankfurt: European Central Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • McCallum, B. (1981). Price level determinacy with an interest rate rule and rational expectations. Journal of Monetary Economics, 8(3), 319–329.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McCallum, B. (2001). Monetary policy analysis in models without money. NBER Working Paper No. 8174.

    Google Scholar 

  • McCallum, B. (2003). Multiple-solution indeterminacies in monetary policy analysis. Journal of Monetary Economics, 50(5), 1153–1175.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meltzer, A.H. (2001). The transmission process. In Deutsche Bundesbank (Ed.), The monetary transmission process: recent developments and lessons for Europe (pp. 112–130). London: Palgrave.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, E. (2002). Direct effects of base money on aggregate demand: theory and evidence. Journal of Monetary Economics, 49(4), 687–708.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, E. (2003). The future of monetary aggregates in monetary policy analysis. Journal of Monetary Economics, 50(5), 1029–1059.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, E. (2007). Comment on: Samuel Reynard, ‘‘Maintaining Low Inflation”. Journal of Monetary Economics, 54(5), 1472–1479.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Neumann, M. (1997). Monetary targeting in Germany. In I. Kuroda (Ed.), Towards more effective monetary policy (pp. 176–210). London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Neumann, M., & Greiber, C. (2004). Inflation and core money growth in the euro area. Deutsche Bundesbank Discussion Paper No. 36/2004.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nicoletti-Altimari, S. (2001). Does money lead inflation in the euro area? ECB Working Paper No. 63.

    Google Scholar 

  • Noyer, C. (2007). Financial innovation, monetary policy, and financial stability, speech, 17 Apr 2007. Available at: http://www.banque-france.fr/gb/instit/telechar/discours/20070428.pdf.

  • OECD (2007). Economic survey of the euro area 2007: the role of monetary aggregates in monetary policy. OECD: Paris.

    Google Scholar 

  • Orphanides, A. (2003). Historical monetary policy analysis and the Taylor rule. Journal of Monetary Economics, 50(5), 983–1022.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Orphanides, A., & Porter, R. (2000). P* revisited: money-based inflation forecasts with a changing equilibrium velocity. Journal of Economics and Business, 52(1/2), 87–100.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Papademos, L. (2006). The role of money in the conduct of monetary policy. In The 4th ECB central banking conference “the role of money: money and monetary policy in the twenty-first century”, Frankfurt am Main, November, 2006. Available at: http://www.ecb.int/press/key/date/2006/html/sp061110.en.html.

  • Pill, H., & Rautanen, T. (2006). Monetary analysis: the ECB experience. mimeo, Frankfurt.

    Google Scholar 

  • Posen, A. (2000). Lessons from the Bundesbank on the occasion of its early retirement. In L. Mahadeva & G. Sterne (Eds.), Monetary policy frameworks in a global context (pp. 393–421). London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Reischle, J. (2007). Recent developments in the net external asset position of German Banks. In ECB workshop “the external dimension of monetary analysis”, Frankfurt/Germany, December 2007.

    Google Scholar 

  • Reuters. (2007). Papademos tritt Zweifeln an EZB-Strategie entgegen. Online News Report, 12 Jun 2007. Available at: http://de.today.reuters.com/news/newsArticle.aspx?type=economicsNews&storyID=2007-06-12T173253Z_01_HUM263163_RTRDEOC_0_EZB-STRATEGIE-PAPADEMOS.xml.

  • Reynard, S. (2007). Maintaining low inflation, money, interest rates, and policy stance. Journal of Monetary Economics, 54(5), 1441–1471.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roffia, B., & Zaghini, A. (2007). Excess money growth and inflation dynamics. ECB Working Paper No. 749.

    Google Scholar 

  • Romer, C., & Romer, D. (1992). New evidence on the monetary transmission mechanism. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 149–198.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rudebusch, G., & Svensson, L. (2002). Eurosystem monetary targeting: lessons from U.S. data. European Economic Review, 46(3), 417–442.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sargent, T., & Wallace, N. (1975). ‘Rational’ expectations, the optimal monetary instrument, and the optimal money supply rule. Journal of Political Economy, 83(2), 241–254.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Scharnagl, M., & Schumacher, C. (2007). Reconsidering the role of monetary indicators for euro area inflation from a Bayesian perspective using group inclusion probabilities. Deutsche Bundesbank Discussion Paper No. 09/2007.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smets, F. (2003). Discussion “Putting ‘M’ back in monetary policy”. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 35(6), 1257–1264.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stavrev, E. (2006). Measures of underlying inflation in the euro area: assessment and role for informing monetary policy. IMF Working Paper No. 06/197.

    Google Scholar 

  • Svensson, L. (2000). Does the P* model provide any rationale for monetary targeting? German Economic Review, 1, 69–81.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Svensson, L.E.O. (2003a). Monetary policy and real stabilization. NBER Working Paper No. 9486.

    Google Scholar 

  • Svensson, L. (2003b). Comment on: Nelson (2003), The future of monetary aggregates in monetary policy. Journal of Monetary Economics, 50, 1061–1070.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tödter, K., & Reimers, H. (1997). P-star as a link between money and prices in Germany. Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, 130, 273–289.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Uhlig, H. (2008). Comment. In: A. Beyer, L. Reichlin (Eds.), The role of money—money and monetary policy in the twenty-first century. Proceedings of the 4th ECB central banking conference (pp. 87–96), 9–10 November 2006, ECB: Frankfurt.

    Google Scholar 

  • Van den Heuvel, S. (2007). The bank capital channel of monetary policy. mimeo. Pennsylvania: University of Pennsylvania.

    Google Scholar 

  • von Hagen, J. (1999). Money growth targeting by the Bundesbank. Journal of Monetary Economics, 43, 681–701.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Woodford, M. (2003). Interest and prices: foundations of a theory of monetary policy. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Woodford, M. (2007). How important is money in the conduct of monetary policy? NBER Working Paper No. 13325.

    Google Scholar 

  • Woodford, M. (2008). Does a “Two-Pillar Phillips Curve” justify a two-pillar monetary policy strategy? In: A. Beyer, L. Reichlin, L. (Eds.), The role of money—money and monetary policy in the twenty-first century. Proceedings of the 4th ECB central banking conference (pp. 56–82), 9–10 November 2006, ECB: Frankfurt.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Helge Berger .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2010 Springer Berlin Heidelberg

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Berger, H., Harjes, T., Stavrev, E. (2010). The ECB’s Monetary Analysis Revisited. In: Haan, J., Berger, H. (eds) The European Central Bank at Ten. Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-14237-6_3

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-14237-6_3

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-642-14236-9

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-642-14237-6

  • eBook Packages: Business and EconomicsEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics