Strategic Style in Pared-Down Poker

Chapter

Abstract

This chapter deals with the manner of making diagnoses and decisions, called strategic style, in a gambling game called Pared-down Poker. The approach treats style as a mental mode in which choices are constrained by expected utilities. The focus is on two classes of utility, i.e., money and effort, and how cognitive styles compare to normative strategies in optimizing these utilities. The insights are applied to real-world concerns like managing the war against terror networks and assessing the risks of system failures. After “Introducing the Interactions” involved in playing poker, the contents are arranged in four sections, as follows. “Underpinnings of Utility” outlines four classes of utility and highlights the differences between them: economic utility (money), ergonomic utility (effort), informatic utility (knowledge), and aesthetic utility (pleasure). “Inference and Investment” dissects the cognitive challenges of playing poker and relates them to real-world situations of business and war, where the key tasks are inference (of cards in poker, or strength in war) and investment (of chips in poker, or force in war) to maximize expected utility. “Strategies and Styles” presents normative (optimal) approaches to inference and investment, and compares them to cognitive heuristics by which people play poker–-focusing on Bayesian methods and how they differ from human styles. The normative strategy is then pitted against cognitive styles in head-to-head tournaments, and tournaments are also held between different styles. The results show that style is ergonomically efficient and economically effective, i.e., style is smart. “Applying the Analysis” explores how style spaces, of the sort used to model individual behavior in Pared-down Poker, might also be applied to real-world problems where organizations evolve in terror networks and accidents arise from system failures.

References

  1. 1.
    Apostolico D (2005) Tournament poker and the art of war. Lyle Stuart, New York, NYGoogle Scholar
  2. 2.
    Barone L, While L (1999) An adaptive learning model for simplified poker using evolutionary algorithms. In: Proceedings of the congress on evolutionary computation, Washington, DC, July 6–9, pp 153–160Google Scholar
  3. 3.
    Bayes T (1763) An essay towards solving a problem in the doctrine of chances. Philos Trans R Soc Lond 53:370–418Google Scholar
  4. 4.
    Bechara A, Damasio H, Tranel D, Damasio A (1997) Deciding advantageously before knowing the advantageous strategy. Science 275:1293–1295CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. 5.
    Bechara A, Damasio H (2002) Decision-making and addiction (Part I): impaired activation of somatic states in substance dependent individuals when pondering decisions with negative future consequences. Neuropsychologia 40:1675–1689CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. 6.
    Bechara A, Dolan S, Hindes A (2002) Decision-making and addiction (Part II): myopia for the future or hypersensitivity to reward. Neuropsychologia 40:1690–1705CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. 7.
    Bernoulli D (1738) Exposition of a new theory of the measurement of risk (trans: Sommer L (1954)). Econometrica 22:23–26Google Scholar
  8. 8.
    Bernstein P (1996) Against the gods: the remarkable story of risk. Wiley, New York, NYGoogle Scholar
  9. 9.
    Billings D, Davidson A, Schaeffer J, Szafron D (2002) The challenge of poker. Artif Intell 134:201–240MATHCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. 10.
    Billings D, Papp D, Schaeffer J, Szafron D (1998) Opponent modeling in poker. In: Proceedings of the conference on artificial intelligence, Madison, WI, July 26–30, pp 493–498Google Scholar
  11. 11.
    Borel É (1938) Traié du calcul des probabiliés et ses applications Volume 4, Fascicule 2, Applications aux jeux des hazard. Gautier-Villars, ParisGoogle Scholar
  12. 12.
    Brandenburger A, Nalebuff B (1996) Co-opetition. Doubleday, New York, NYGoogle Scholar
  13. 13.
    Burns K (2007) EVE’s entropy: a formal gauge of fun in games. Stud Comput Intell 71:153–173CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. 14.
    Burns K (2007) Dealing with probabilities: on improving inferences with Bayesian boxes. In: Hoffman R (ed) Expertise out of context. Lawrence Erlbaum, New York, NYGoogle Scholar
  15. 15.
    Burns K (2006) Atoms of EVE’: a Bayesian basis for aesthetic analysis of style in sketching. Artif Intell Eng Des Anal Manufac 20:185–199Google Scholar
  16. 16.
    Burns K (2006) Style in poker. In: Proceedings of the IEEE conference on computational intelligence in games, Reno, NV, May 22–24, pp 257–264Google Scholar
  17. 17.
    Burns K (2006) Bayesian inference in disputed authorship: a case study of cognitive errors and a new system for decision support. Info Sci 176:1570–1589MATHCrossRefMathSciNetGoogle Scholar
  18. 18.
    Burns K (2005) Pared-down poker: cutting to the core of command and control. Proceedings of the IEEE conference on computational intelligence in games, pp 234–241Google Scholar
  19. 19.
    Burns K (2004) Heads-up face-off: on style and skill in the game of poker. Papers from the AAAI symposium on style and meaning in language, art, music, and design, FS-4-07. AAAI Press, Menlo Park, CA, pp 15–22Google Scholar
  20. 20.
    Burns K, Demaree H (2009) A chance to learn: On matching probabilities to optimize utilities. Info Sci 179:1599–1607CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. 21.
    Burns K, Bonaceto C (2006) Structure mapping in visual displays for decision support. Paper presented at the 11th international command and control research and technology symposium, San Diego, CA, June 20–22,Google Scholar
  22. 22.
    Burns K, Dubnov S (2006) Memex music and gambling games: EVE’s take on lucky number 13. In: Proceedings of the AAAI workshop on computational aesthetics, WS-06-04. AAAI Press, Menlo Park, CA, pp 30–36Google Scholar
  23. 23.
    Camerer C (2003) Behavioral game theory: experiments in strategic interaction. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJGoogle Scholar
  24. 24.
    Cancho R, Solé R (2003) Least effort and the origins of scaling in human language. Proc Natl Acad Sci USA 100(3):788–791MATHCrossRefMathSciNetGoogle Scholar
  25. 25.
    Connolly T, Arkes H, Hammond K (eds) (2000) Judgment and decision making: An interdisciplinary reader. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UKGoogle Scholar
  26. 26.
    Csikszentmihalyi M (1991) Flow: the psychology of optimal experience. Harper Collins, New York, NYGoogle Scholar
  27. 27.
    Davis M (1997) Game theory. Dover, New York, NYGoogle Scholar
  28. 28.
    Davis P (2001) Effects-based operations: a grand challenge for the analytical community, MR-1477-USJFCOM/AF. RAND Corporation, Santa Monica, CAGoogle Scholar
  29. 29.
    Edwards W (1954) The theory of decision making. Psychol Bull 41:380–417CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  30. 30.
    Edwards W (1961) Behavioral decision theory. Ann Rev Psychol 12:473–498CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  31. 31.
    Edwards W, Newman J (1982) Multi-attribute evaluation. Sage, Beverly Hills, CAGoogle Scholar
  32. 32.
    Ferguson C, Ferguson T (2003) On the Borel and von Neumann poker models. Game Theory Applications 9:17–32MathSciNetGoogle Scholar
  33. 33.
    Ferguson C, Ferguson T, Gawargy C (2004) Uniform (0,1) two-person poker models. UCLA Department of mathematics. http://www.math.ucla.edu/ \(\sim \)tom/papers/poker2.pdf. Accessed 15 Mar 2006
  34. 34.
    Finucane M, Alhakami A, Slovic P, Johnson S (2000) The affect heuristic in judgments of risks and benefits. J Behav Decis Mak 13:1–17CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  35. 35.
    Gärdenfors P (2004) Conceptual spaces: the geometry of thought. MIT Press, Cambridge, MAGoogle Scholar
  36. 36.
    Gattis M (2001) Spatial schemas and abstract thought. MIT Press, Cambridge, MAGoogle Scholar
  37. 37.
    Gentner D (1983) Structure mapping: a theoretical framework for analogy. Cogn Sci 7: 155–170CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  38. 38.
    Gentner D, Markman A (1997) Structure mapping in analogy and similarity. Am Psychol 52(1):45–56CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  39. 39.
    Gigerenzer G, Todd P (1999) Simple heuristics that make us smart. Oxford University Press, New York, NYGoogle Scholar
  40. 40.
    Hamilton S, Garber L (1997) Deep Blue’s hardware-software synergy. IEEE Comput 30(1):29–35CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  41. 41.
    Harford T (2006) The poker machine. Financ Times Mag 6 May 2006:16–21Google Scholar
  42. 42.
    Hellmuth P (2003) Play poker like the pros. Harper Collins, New York, NYGoogle Scholar
  43. 43.
    Herrnstein R (1997) The matching law: papers in psychology and economics. In: Rachlin H, Laibson D (eds) Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MAGoogle Scholar
  44. 44.
    Kahneman D, Tversky A (1979) Prospect theory: an analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica 47(2):263–291MATHCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  45. 45.
    Kahneman D, Slovic P, Tversky A (eds) (1982) Judgment under uncertainty: heuristics and biases. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeGoogle Scholar
  46. 46.
    Kendall G, Willdig M (2001) An investigation of an adaptive poker player. In: Proceedings of the Australian joint conference on artificial intelligence, LNAI-2256, Adelaide, SA, Australia, Dec 10–14, pp 189–200Google Scholar
  47. 47.
    Keys R (2007) Address to the air force association. Air warfare symposium, Lake Buena Vista, FL, 8 Feb 2007Google Scholar
  48. 48.
    Klein, G. (1998) Sources of power: how people make decisions. MIT Press, Cambridge, MAGoogle Scholar
  49. 49.
    Kleinmuntz B (1990) Why we still use our heads instead of formulas: toward an integrative approach. Psychol Bull 107:296–310CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  50. 50.
    Knill D, Richards W (eds) (1996) Perception as Bayesian inference. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeGoogle Scholar
  51. 51.
    Koller D, Pfeffer A (1997) Representations and solutions for game-theoretic problems. Artif Intell 94(1):167–215MATHCrossRefMathSciNetGoogle Scholar
  52. 52.
    Korb K, Nicholson A, Jitnah N (1999) Bayesian poker. In: Proceedings of the conference on uncertainty in artificial intelligence, Stockholm, Sweden, July 30–August 1, pp 343–350Google Scholar
  53. 53.
    Kuhn H (1950) A simplified two-person poker. In: Kuhn H, Tucker A (eds) Contributions to the theory of games, Vol. 1. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ, (pp 97–103)Google Scholar
  54. 54.
    Kumamoto H, Henley E (1996) Probabilistic risk assessment and management for engineers and scientists. IEEE Press, New York, NYGoogle Scholar
  55. 55.
    Lakoff G (1987) Women, fire, and dangerous things: what categories reveal about the mind. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, ILGoogle Scholar
  56. 56.
    Lakoff G, Johnson M (1980) Metaphors we live by. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, ILGoogle Scholar
  57. 57.
    Leedom D (2004) The analytic representation of sensemaking and knowledge management within a military C2 organization, AFRL-HE-WP-TR-2004-0083. United States Air Force Research Laboratory, WPAFB, OHGoogle Scholar
  58. 58.
    Loewenstein G, Weber E, Hsee C, Welch N (2001) Risk as feelings. Psychol Bull 127(2): 267–286CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  59. 59.
    Mandeles M, Hone T, Terry S (1996) Managing command and control in the Persian Gulf war. Praeger, Westport, CTGoogle Scholar
  60. 60.
    McDonald J (1950) Strategy in poker, business, and war. Norton, New York, NYGoogle Scholar
  61. 61.
    McKenna J (2006) Beyond bluffs: master the mysteries of poker. Kensington, New York, NYGoogle Scholar
  62. 62.
    McKenna J (2005) Beyond tells: power poker psychology. Kensington, New York, NYGoogle Scholar
  63. 63.
    McManus J (2003) Positively fifth street: murderers, cheetahs, and Binion’s world series of poker. Farrar, Straus, & Giroux, New York, NYGoogle Scholar
  64. 64.
    Montague R (2006) Why choose this book? How we make decisions. Dutton, New York, NYGoogle Scholar
  65. 65.
    Morgan M, Fischhoff B, Bostrom A, Atman C (2002) Risk communication: a mental models approach. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UKGoogle Scholar
  66. 66.
    Nash J (1950) Equilibrium points in N-person games. Proc Natl Acad Sci 36(1):48–49MATHCrossRefMathSciNetGoogle Scholar
  67. 67.
    Payne J, Bettman J, Johnson E (1993) The adaptive decision maker. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UKCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  68. 68.
    Pearl J (2000) Causality: models, reasoning, and inference. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UKGoogle Scholar
  69. 69.
    Perrow C (1984) Normal accidents: living with high-risk technologies. Basic Books, New York, NYGoogle Scholar
  70. 70.
    Pirolli P (2007) Information foraging theory: adaptive interaction with information. Oxford University Press, New York, NYCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  71. 71.
    Post T, Van den Assem M, Baltussen G, Thaler R (2008) Deal or no deal? Decision making under risk in a large-payoff game show. Am Econ Rev, 98(1):38–71CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  72. 72.
    Postrel V (2003) The substance of style. Harper Collins, New York, NYGoogle Scholar
  73. 73.
    Richards W (ed) (1988) Natural computation. MIT Press, Cambridge, MAGoogle Scholar
  74. 74.
    Samuelson P (2004) Heads, I win, and tails, you lose. In: von Neumann J, Morgenstern O (1944) Theory of games and economic behavior, sixtieth-anniversary edition. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ, pp 675–676Google Scholar
  75. 75.
    Schaeffer J (1996) One jump ahead: challenging human supremacy in checkers. Springer, New York, NYGoogle Scholar
  76. 76.
    Schoonmaker A (2000) The psychology of poker. Two Plus Two Publishing, Las Vegas, NVGoogle Scholar
  77. 77.
    Shannon C, Weaver W (1949) The mathematical theory of communication. University of Illinois Press, Urbana, ILGoogle Scholar
  78. 78.
    Shapiro J (2005) Organizing terror: hierarchy and networks in covert organizations. Paper presented at the annual meeting of the American political science association, Washington, DC, 1 Sep 2005Google Scholar
  79. 79.
    Shi J, Littman M (2000) Abstraction methods for game-theoretic poker. In: Proceedings of the 2nd international conference on computers and games, Hamamatsu, Japan, October 26–28, pp 333–345Google Scholar
  80. 80.
    Sklansky D (1987) The theory of poker. Two Plus Two Publishing, Las Vegas, NVGoogle Scholar
  81. 81.
    Smith E (2006) Complexity, networking, and effects-based approaches to operations. CCRP Publication Series, DoD Command and Control Research Program, Washington, DCGoogle Scholar
  82. 82.
    Southey F, Bowling M, Larson B, Piccione C, Burch N, Billings D, Rayner C (2005) Bayes bluff: opponent modeling in poker. In: Proceedings of the conference on uncertainty in artificial intelligence, Edinburgh, Scotland, July 26–29, pp 550–558Google Scholar
  83. 83.
    Specter M (1996) 10 years later, through fear, Chernobyl still kills in Belarus. New York Times, p 1Google Scholar
  84. 84.
    Sun-tzu (2002) The art of war (trans: Minford J). Viking Penguin, New York, NYGoogle Scholar
  85. 85.
    Tenenbaum J, Griffiths T, Kemp C (2006) Theory-based Bayesian models of inductive learning and reasoning. Trends Cogn Sci 10(7):309–318CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  86. 86.
    Tetlock P (2003) Thinking the unthinkable: sacred values and taboo cognitions. Trends Cogn Sci 7(7):320–324CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  87. 87.
    True D, Leaver D, Fenstermacher E, Gaertner J (2003) Risk characterization of the potential consequences of an armed terrorist ground attack on a U.S. nuclear power plant. EPRI Report for the Nuclear Energy InstituteGoogle Scholar
  88. 88.
    Tversky A, Kahneman D (1992) Advances in prospect theory: cumulative representation of uncertainty. J Risk Uncertainty 5:297–323MATHCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  89. 89.
    von Neumann J, Morgenstern O (1944) Theory of games and economic behavior. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJGoogle Scholar
  90. 90.
    Weick K (1995) Sensemaking in organizations. Sage, Beverly Hills, CAGoogle Scholar
  91. 91.
    Wolf F, Berniker E (1999) Validating normal accident theory: chemical accidents, fires, and explosions in petroleum refineries. Paper presented at the high consequences system surety conference, Sandia National Laboratory, Albuquerque, NM, 11–14, Nov 1999Google Scholar
  92. 92.
    Zsambok C, Klein G (1997) Naturalistic decision making. Lawrence Erlbaum Associates, Mahwah, NJGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg 2010

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.The MITRE CorporationBedfordUSA

Personalised recommendations