Skip to main content

Proximity, Social Capital and the Simon Model of Stochastic Growth

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Complexity and Spatial Networks

Part of the book series: Advances in Spatial Science ((ADVSPATIAL))

Abstract

It is customary to define economic geography as a discipline that deals with the uneven distribution of economic activity across space. From a historical perspective, stochastic growth models are of particular use (Simon 1955). Such models explain the current distribution of activities from the dynamics of the long historical process that has produced these patterns. This approach might also be labelled “evolutionary economic geography” (Boschma and Frenken 2006), referring to the evolutionary economics tradition, since stochastic growth models account for path dependence in which each event changes the probability of a next event to occur (Arthur 1989; David 1985).

In geography, stochastic models of urban growth have a long intellectual history. In particular, The Simon model of the Zipf's rank-size rule is still regarded as one of the canonical models of urban size distribution (Batty 2005). A shortcoming of these urban growth models is that they take spatial entities as the unit of analysis. Since spatial entities are not behavioural entities, the explanation of urban growth in such models is not grounded in the micro-behaviour of agents. What is more, the delineation of spatial entities is a notoriously difficult exercise. Organizational units are less problematic, because these are the agents of change and relatively easy, though by no means trivial, to delineate. More recently, some of the urban growth models have explicit micro-foundations, including neoclassical models (Duranton and Puga 2004) and agent-based models (Batty 2005).

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

eBook
USD 16.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    See Pumain (2006, p. 202): “The proportionality between resident population and inward and outward migratory flows which is derived from the multiplication of the population at the origin by the population at destination in the numerator of the model can be seen as merely an application of a random interaction process”.

  2. 2.

    Put differently, the probability of a product division producing a new entrepreneur who sets up his or her own product division is proportional to the number of previous employees who set up an own product division, an example of preferential attachment where the probability that a node acquires a new link is proportional to the node's degree (Barabási and Albert 1999).

References

  • Arthur WB (1989) Competing technologies, increasing returns, and lock-in by historical events. Econ J 99:116–131

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barabási A-L, Albert R (1999) Emergence of scaling in random networks. Science 286:509–512

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bathelt H, Malmberg A, Maskell P (2004) Clusters and knowledge: Local buzz, global pipelines and the process of knowledge creation. Prog Hum Geogr 28:31–56

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Batty M (2005) Cities and complexity. Understanding cities with cellular atomata, agent-based models, and fractals MIT Press, Harvard, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Boschma RA (2004) The competitiveness of regions from an evolutionary perspective. Reg Stud 38(9):1001–1014

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boschma RA (2005) Proximity and innovation. A critical assessment. Reg Stud 39(1):61–74

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boschma RA, Frenken K (2006) Why is economic geography not an evolutionary science? Towards an evolutionary economic geography. J Econ Geogr 6(3):273–302

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Breschi S, Lissoni F (2003) Mobility and social networks: Localised knowledge spillovers revisited. CESPRI Working Paper 142. http://www.cespri.unibocconi.it/, forthcoming in the Annales d'Economie et de Statistique

  • Breschi S, Lissoni F (2006) Mobility of inventors and the geography of knowledge spillovers. New evidence on US data. CESPRI Working Paper 184. http://www.cespri.unibocconi.it/

  • Castells M (1996) The rise of the network society. Blackwell, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • David PA (1985) The economics of QWERTY. Am Econ Rev (Papers and Proceedings) 75:332–337

    Google Scholar 

  • Duranton G, Puga D (2004) Micro-foundations of urban agglomeration economies. In: Henderson JV, Thisse JF (eds) Handbook of regional and urban economics, 1st ed., vol 4. Elsevier: Amsterdam, pp 2063–2117

    Google Scholar 

  • Frenken K, Boschma RA (2007) A theoretical framework for evolutionary economic geography: industrial dynamics and urban growth as a branching process. J Econ Geogr 7(5):635–649

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krugman PR (1991) Increasing returns and economic geography. J Polit Econ 99(3):483–499

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ponds R, van Oort FG, Frenken K (2007) The geographical and institutional proximity of research collaboration. Pap Reg Sci 86:423–443

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pumain D (2006) Alternative explanations of hierarchical differentiation in urban systems. In: Pumain D (ed.) Hierarchy in natural and social sciences. Springer, Dordrecht, pp 169–222

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Scott AJ (2001) Global city-regions. Trends, theory, policy. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Simon HA (1955) On a class of skew distribution functions. Biometrika 42(3–4):425–440

    Google Scholar 

  • Tinbergen J (1962) The world economy. Suggestions for an international economic policy. Twentieth Century Fund, New York, NY

    Google Scholar 

  • Wilson AG (1970) Entropy in urban and regional modelling. Pion, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Zipf G (1949) Human behavior and the principle of least effort. Addison-Wesley, Cambridge MA

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2009 Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Frenken, K. (2009). Proximity, Social Capital and the Simon Model of Stochastic Growth. In: Reggiani, A., Nijkamp, P. (eds) Complexity and Spatial Networks. Advances in Spatial Science. Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-01554-0_10

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-01554-0_10

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-642-01553-3

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-642-01554-0

  • eBook Packages: Business and EconomicsEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics