Skip to main content

Unemployment Expectations in an Agent-Based Model with Education

  • Conference paper
  • First Online:

Part of the book series: Lecture Notes in Computer Science ((LNAI,volume 10978))

Abstract

Why are unemployment expectations of the “man in the street” markedly different from professional forecasts? We present an agent-based model to explain this deep disconnection using boundedly rational agents with different levels of education. A good fit of empirical data is obtained under the assumptions that there is staggered update of information, agents update episodically their estimate and there is a fraction of households who always and stubbornly forecast that the unemployment is going to raise. The model also sheds light on the role of education and suggests that more educated agents update their information more often and less obstinately fixate on the worst possible forecast.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   39.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD   54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    By professional forecasts in this paper we refer to the figures made public by OECD every quarter. The use of a specific set of “professional” forecasts is not affecting the results sensibly as other forecasts, say produced by different research centers or governmental offices, are typically very similar and strongly correlated with the OECD data.

  2. 2.

    There are several micro-level empirical studies on this topic, for example Lusardi and Mitchell [11], Souleles [12] and Easaw et al. [13].

  3. 3.

    “Remain the same” and “do not know” are both encoded as zero.

  4. 4.

    A “balance index” is constructed as the difference between the percentages of respondents giving positive and negative replies.

  5. 5.

    From 2003, OECD releases forecasts also for each quarter, while for the period from 1995 to 2002 OECD releases forecasts only for each semester. Therefore until 2002 we estimate the missing quarters forecasts through interpolation of the biannual forecasts.

  6. 6.

    2000 individuals are interviewed by ISTAT per month (6000 individuals per quarter). About \(\frac{1}{2}\) of the Italian population belongs to the lths group, about \(\frac{1}{3}\) to the hs group and about \(\frac{1}{6}\) to the col group. Hence, the baseline simulation has 3000 agents per quarter with lths, 2000 with hs and 1000 with col.

  7. 7.

    The code can be downloaded at http://virgo.unive.it/paolop/epidemics-istat-paams.nlogo.

  8. 8.

    In the interpretation of the results, it has to be remembered that some of the individuals (on average, a fraction \(\lambda ^{edu}\cdot \mu ^{edu}\)) receive the signal \(o_t\) but still provide a stubbornly pessimistic answer. This implies that the fraction of individuals who receive the signal \(o_t\) and really incorporate it into the answer \(ans_{it}\) is approximately \(\lambda ^{edu}\cdot (1-\mu ^{edu})\), that is 0.059 for lths, 0.070 for hs and 0.083 for col.

References

  1. Carroll, C.D., Hall, R.E., Zeldes, S.P.: The buffer-stock theory of saving: some macroeconomic evidence. Brookings Papers Econ. Act. 1992(2), 61–156 (1992)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  2. Hegselmann, R., Krause, U.: Opinion dynamics and bounded confidence models, analysis, and simulation. J. Artif. Soc. Soc. Simul. 5(3) (2002)

    Google Scholar 

  3. Castellano, C., Fortunato, S., Loreto, V.: Statistical physics of social dynamics. Rev. Modern Phys. 81(2), 591 (2009)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  4. Hegselmann, R., König, S., Kurz, S., Niemann, C., Rambau, J.: Optimal opinion control: the campaign problem. J. Artif. Soc. Soc. Simul. 18(3) (2015)

    Google Scholar 

  5. Carroll, C.D.: The epidemiology of macroeconomic expectations. In: Blume, L.E., Durlauf, S.N. (eds.) The Economy as an Evolving Complex System, III: Current Perspectives and Future Directions, pp. 5–29. Oxford University Press, Oxford (2006)

    Google Scholar 

  6. Rabin, M.: Psychology and economics. J. Econ. Lit. 36(1), 11–46 (1998)

    Google Scholar 

  7. Camerer, C.F.: Progress in behavioral game theory. J. Econ. Perspect. 11(4), 167–188 (1997)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  8. Branch, W.A.: The theory of rationally heterogeneous expectations: evidence from survey data on inflation expectations. Econ. J. 114(497), 592–621 (2004)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  9. Axtell, R.L., Epstein, J.M.: Coordination in Transient Social Networks: An Agent-Based Computational Model of the Timing of Retirement, pp. 161–183. Brookings Institution Press, Washington DC (1999)

    Google Scholar 

  10. Moro, A., Pellizzari, P.: A computational model of labor market participation with health shocks and bounded rationality. Knowl. Inf. Syst. 54(3), 617–631 (2018)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  11. Lusardi, A., Mitchell, O.S.: Financial literacy around the world: an overview. J. Pension Econ. Financ. 10(4), 497–508 (2011)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  12. Souleles, N.S.: Expectations, heterogeneous forecast errors, and consumption: micro evidence from the Michigan consumer sentiment surveys. J. Money Credit Bank. 36(1), 39–72 (2004)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  13. Easaw, J., Golinelli, R., Malgarini, M.: What determines households inflation expectations? Theory and evidence from a household survey. Eur. Econ. Rev. 61, 1–13 (2013)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  14. Epstein, J.M.: Why model? J. Artif. Soc. Soc. Simul. 11(4), 12 (2008)

    Google Scholar 

  15. Epstein, J.M.: Generative Social Science: Studies in Agent-Based Computational Modeling. Princeton University Press, Princeton (2006)

    Book  Google Scholar 

  16. Capistrán, C., Timmermann, A.: Disagreement and biases in inflation expectations. J. Money Credit Bank. 41(2–3), 365–396 (2009)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  17. Wilensky, U.: NetLogo (1999). http://ccl.northwestern.edu/netlogo/. Center for Connected Learning and Computer-Based Modeling, Northwestern University, Evanston, IL

  18. Conlisk, J.: Why bounded rationality. J. Econ. Lit. 34, 669–700 (1996)

    Google Scholar 

  19. Baddeley, M.: Herding, social influence and economic decision-making: socio-psychological and neuroscientific analyses. Philos. Trans. Roy. Soc. Lond. B: Biol. Sci. 365(1538), 281–290 (2010)

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Luca Gerotto .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2018 Springer International Publishing AG, part of Springer Nature

About this paper

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this paper

Gerotto, L., Pellizzari, P. (2018). Unemployment Expectations in an Agent-Based Model with Education. In: Demazeau, Y., An, B., Bajo, J., Fernández-Caballero, A. (eds) Advances in Practical Applications of Agents, Multi-Agent Systems, and Complexity: The PAAMS Collection. PAAMS 2018. Lecture Notes in Computer Science(), vol 10978. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-94580-4_14

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-94580-4_14

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Cham

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-319-94579-8

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-319-94580-4

  • eBook Packages: Computer ScienceComputer Science (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics