Skip to main content

Agent-Based Modeling of Family Formation and Dissolution

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Analytical Family Demography

Part of the book series: The Springer Series on Demographic Methods and Population Analysis ((PSDE,volume 47))

Abstract

Patterns of family formation and dissolution are typically assumed to derive from an interplay between the structure of the marriage market and people’s partner preferences. One challenge that family researchers often face is that they have no direct measures of the preferences that have guided the partnering decisions that underlie observed family patterns. This is particularly the case when the interest is in long-term changes that have started before survey data about such preferences became available. This chapter introduces agent-based computational (ABC) modeling as a way to deal with this challenge. In ABC modeling, researchers make explicit assumptions about the constraints and preferences that guide people’s partnering decisions. These assumptions are then translated into formal models that are submitted to computational simulations of familial behavior in potentially large and heterogeneous populations, along with relevant and available empirical information. The results of these simulations make it possible to (1) assess whether a given set of preferences may have plausibly been involved in generating observed familial behavior given the constraints that people face and (2) to assess whether very different sets of preferences may generate similar patterns. We illustrate these capabilities of ABC modeling with three examples from our own research in the areas of assortative mating and divorce.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 129.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Here we describe only the most important aspects of the model. Additional details are provided in Grow and Van Bavel (2015).

  2. 2.

    We chose this simulation period based on the empirical input data that was available for initializing the model; see details below.

  3. 3.

    Technically, a i increases by one in every simulation step. Considering that each simulation step represents a 10th of a year, a i ranges from 0 to 800 and the value 800 represents the age 80 years.

  4. 4.

    The average age difference to the disadvantage of wives reported by England and McClintock (2009) increased with the age-at-marriage of husbands, but this increase leveled off for husbands who married after their 30s. As suggested by England and McClintock (2009), this can happen when women are aversive of marrying men who are much older than they are, which makes it more difficult for older men to actually find a young partner who is willing to marry them.

  5. 5.

    In Grow and Van Bavel (2015) u i is denoted α i ; we changed this here to avoid confusing this variable with a i .

  6. 6.

    Technically, agents are selected one after the other (without replacement) to seek out somebody else in a given simulation step. Hence, it can happen that a given agent encounters multiple others in one simulation step.

  7. 7.

    European Social Survey Rounds 5 and 6 Data (2010–2012). Norwegian Social Science Data Services, Norway—Data Archive and distributor of ESS data for ESS ERIC.

  8. 8.

    The exact parameterization for female agents (f) was w s f =.385, w y f =1.201, and w a f =10.833; for male agents (m), the parameter values were w s m =.934, w y m =1.025, and w a m =5.009. The larger value of w a f compared to w a m is congruent with the observation that women tend to marry men who are on average 2–3 years older, regardless of their own age (indicating less lenient age preferences), whereas men tend to marry women who are increasingly younger than themselves, but also increasingly older than the ideal of 24 years, as they grow older (indicating more lenient age preferences). This greater leniency among men may be partly owed to the fact that as they grow older themselves, it becomes more and more difficult for them to find women who are in their mid-20s and who are willing to form unions with them.

  9. 9.

    As we show in Grow and Van Bavel (2015), these results are robust to changes in the preference structures that the model assumes to underlie partner search. More specifically, in a separate sensitivity analysis, we ‘switched off’ agents’ preferences for each of the different partner characteristics one at a time, by setting the corresponding exponents to 0. For example, to assess we effect that the models’ assumptions related to agents’ age preferences have on model outcomes net of all other assumptions, we set w a m = w a f =0 (which implies that agents would not care at all about the age of their partners), while leaving all other parameters unchanged. The fact that our main results were qualitatively not affected implies that model outcomes are not contingent on one specific assumption related to agents’ partner preferences.

  10. 10.

    See Grow and Van Bavel (2017) for details on the sample selection. Given that in Europe unmarried cohabitation is becoming increasingly prevalent and in some countries even has attained a meaning similar to marriage (Hiekel et al. 2014), some scholars have combined both union types in their analysis of relative household incomes across Europe (Klesment and Van Bavel 2017; Van Bavel and Klesment 2017). For comparability, we also used this approach here.

  11. 11.

    If everybody strives for partners with high-quality characteristics, people with the highest-quality characteristics will be in the best position to attract partners with high-quality characteristics. This renders it likely that men and women with the highest-quality characteristics will form unions with each other first. Once these individuals are removed from the partner market, those who occupy the highest ranks in the new quality distribution will form unions with each other next, and so on.

  12. 12.

    Members of the proposing sex can exhaust their list of alternatives before being matched if the sex-ratio is imbalanced so that there is a shortage of opposite-sex members.

  13. 13.

    For example, in linear regression models, the explained variance in the outcome tends to increase with the number of variables that are included in the model, even if none of these variables are causally related to the outcome.

References

  • Aboim, S. (2010). Gender cultures and the division of labour in contemporary Europe: A cross-national perspective. The Sociological Review, 58(2), 171–196.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Amato, P. R., & Previti, D. (2003). People’s reasons for divorcing: Gender, social class, the life course, and adjustment. Journal of Family Issues, 24(5), 602–626.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Axinn, W. G., & Thornton, A. (1993). Mothers, children, and cohabitation: The intergenerational effects of attitudes and behavior. American Sociological Review, 58(2), 233–246.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. S. (1981). A treatise on the family. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bennett, N. G. (2017). A reflection on the changing dynamics of union formation and dissolution. Demographic Research, 36, 371–390.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bertrand, M., Kamenica, E., & Pan, J. (2015). Gender identity and relative income within households. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 130(2), 571–614.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bijak, J., Hilton, J., Silverman, E., & Cao, V. D. (2013). Reforging the wedding ring: Exploring a semi-artificial model of population for the United Kingdom with Gaussian process emulators. Demographic Research, 29, 729–765.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Billari, F. C., Ongaro, F., & Prskawetz, A. (2003). Introduction: Agent-based computational demography. In F. C. Billari & A. Prskawetz (Eds.), Agent-based computational demography: Using simulation to improve our understanding of demographic behaviour (pp. 1–17). Heidelberg: Physica Verlag.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Blossfeld, H.-P. (2009). Educational assortative marriage in comparative perspective. Annual Review of Sociology, 35, 513–530.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blossfeld, H.-P., & Timm, A. (Eds.). (2003). Who marries whom? Educational systems as marriage markets in modern societies. Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bumpass, L. L. (1990). What’s happening to the family? Interactions between demogrpahic and institutional change. Demography, 27(4), 483–498.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buss, D. M. (1989). Sex differences in human mate preferences: Evolutionary hypotheses tested in 37 cultures. Behavioral and Brain Sciences, 12(1), 1–14.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buss, D. M., Abbott, M., Angleitner, A., Asherian, A., Biaggio, A., Blanco-Villasenor, A., et al. (1990). International preferences in selecting mates: A study of 37 cultures. Journal of Cross-Cultural Psychology, 21(1), 5–47.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cobb, C. W., & Douglas, P. H. (1928). A theory of production. The American Economic Review, 18(1), 139–165.

    Google Scholar 

  • Courgeau, D., Bijak, J., Franck, R., & Silverman, E. (2016). Model-based demography: Towards a research agenda. In A. Grow & J. Van Bavel (Eds.), Agent-based modelling in population studies: Concepts, methods, and applications (pp. 29–51). Cham: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • De Hauw, Y., Grow, A., & Van Bavel, J. (2017). The reversed gender gap in education and assortative mating in Europe. European Journal of Population, 33(4), 445–474.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eagly, A. H., Eastwick, P. W., & Johannesen-Schmidt, M. (2009). Possible selves in marital roles: The impact of the anticipated division of labor on the mate preferences of women and men. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin, 35(4), 403–414.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Edwards, J. N. (1969). Familial behavior as social exchange. Journal of Marriage and Family, 31(3), 518–526.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • England, P., & McClintock, E. A. (2009). The gendered double standard of aging in US marriage markets. Population and Development Review, 35(4), 797–816.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Epstein, J. M. (2008). Why model? Journal of Artificial Societies and Social Simulation, 11(4), 12.

    Google Scholar 

  • Epstein, B., & Forber, P. (2013). The perils of tweaking: How to use macrodata to set parameters in complex simulation models. Synthese, 190(2), 203–218.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Esteve, A., García-Román, J., & Permanyer, I. (2012). The gender-gap reversal in education and its effect on union formation: The end of hypergamy? Population and Development Review, 38(3), 535–546.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Esteve, A., Schwartz, C. R., Van Bavel, J., Permanyer, I., Klesment, M., & García-Román, J. (2016). The end of hypergamy: Global trends and implications. Population and Development Review, 42(4), 615–625.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feld, S. L. (1981). The focused organization of social ties. American Journal of Sociology, 86(5), 1015–1035.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Finkel, E. J., Eastwick, P. W., & Matthews, J. (2007). Speed-dating as an invaluable tool for studying romantic attraction: A methodological primer. Personal Relationships, 14(1), 149–166.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fisman, R., Iyengar, S. S., Kamenica, E., & Simonson, I. (2006). Gender differences in mate selection: Evidence from a speed dating experiment. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 121(2), 673–697.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gale, D., & Shapley, L. S. (1962). College admissions and the stability of marriage. The American Mathematical Monthly, 69(1), 9–15.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gilbert, N., & Troitzsch, K. G. (2005). Simulation for the social scientist. Maidenhead: Open University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Glick, P. C., & Landau, E. (1950). Age as a factor in marriage. American Sociological Review, 15(4), 517–529.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goldin, C. (2014). A grand gender convergence: Its last chapter. American Economic Review, 104(4), 1091–1119.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grimm, V., Revilla, E., Berger, U., Jeltsch, F., Mooij, W. M., Railsback, S. F., et al. (2005). Pattern-oriented modeling of agent-based complex systems: Lessons from ecology. Science, 310(5750), 987–991.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grow, A. (2016). Regression metamodels for sensitivity analysis in agent-based computational demography. In A. Grow & J. Van Bavel (Eds.), Agent-based modelling in population studies: Concepts, methods, and application (pp. 185–210). Cham: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grow, A., & Van Bavel, J. (2015). Assortative mating and the reversal of gender inequality in education in Europe: An agent-based model. PLoS ONE, 10(6), e0127806.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grow, A., & Van Bavel, J. (2017). The income cliff in households: Insights from agent-based computational modelling. Paper presented at the 13th conference of the European Sociological Association, Athens, Greece.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grow, A., & Van Bavel, J. (2018). Agent-based modeling. In M. Davidian, R. S. Kenett, N. Longford, G. Molenberghs, W. Piegorsch, & F. Ruggeri (Eds.), Wiley StatsRef: Statistics Reference Online. Hoboken: John Wiley & Sons.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grow, A., Schnor, C., & Van Bavel, J. (2017). The reversal of the gender gap in education and relative divorce risks: A matter of alternatives in partner choice? Population Studies, 71(S1), S15–S34.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hiekel, N., Liefbroer, A. C., & Poortman, A.-R. (2014). Understanding diversity in the meaning of cohabitation across Europe. European Journal of Population, 30(4), 391–410.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hilton, J., & Bijak, J. (2016). Design and analysis of demographic simulations. In A. Grow & J. Van Bavel (Eds.), Agent-based modelling in population studies: Concepts, methods, and applications (pp. 211–235). Cham: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hitsch, G. J., Hortaçsu, A., & Ariely, D. (2010a). What makes you click?—Mate preferences in online dating. Quantitative Marketing and Economics, 8(4), 393–427.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hitsch, G. J., Hortaçsu, A., & Ariely, D. (2010b). Matching and sorting in online dating. American Economic Review, 100(1), 130–163.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hout, M. (1982). The association between husbands’ and wives’ occupations in two-earner families. American Journal of Sociology, 88(2), 397–409.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jalovaara, M. (2012). Socio-economic resources and first-union formation in Finland, cohorts born 1969–81. Population Studies, 66(1), 69–85.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kalmijn, M. (1991). Status homogamy in the United States. American Journal of Sociology, 97(2), 496–523.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kalmijn, M. (1994). Assortative mating by cultural and economic occupational status. American Journal of Sociology, 100(2), 422–452.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kalmijn, M. (1998). Intermarriage and homogamy: Causes, patterns, trends. Annual Review of Sociology, 24, 395–421.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kalmijn, M. (2013). The educational gradient in marriage: A comparison of 25 European countries. Demography, 50(4), 1499–1520.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kalmijn, M., & Flap, H. (2001). Assortative meeting and mating: Unintended consequences of organized settings of partner choice. Social Forces, 79(4), 1289–1312.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • KC, S., Barakat, B., Goujon, A., Skirbekk, V., Sanderson, W. C., & Lutz, W. (2010). Projection of populations by level of educational attainment, age, and sex for 120 countries for 2005–2050. Demographic Research, 22, 383–472.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kenrick, D. T., & Keefe, R. C. (1992). Age preferences in mates reflect sex differences in human reproductive strategies. Behavioral and Brain Sciences, 15(1), 75–91.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kenrick, D. T., Groth, G. E., Trost, M. R., & Sadalla, E. K. (1993). Integrating evolutionary and social exchange perspectives on relationships: Effects of gender, self-appraisal, and involvement level on mate selection criteria. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 64(6), 951–969.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kleijnen, J. P. C. (2008). Design and analysis of simulation experiments. Boston: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Klesment, M., & Van Bavel, J. (2017). The reversal of the gender gap in education, motherhood, and women as main earners in Europe. European Sociological Review, 33(3), 465–481.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lesthaeghe, R. (2014). The second demographic transition: A concise overview of its development. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 111(51), 18112–18115.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lewis, K. (2016). Preferences in the early stages of mate choice. Social Forces, 95(1), 283–320.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li, N. P., & Kenrick, D. T. (2006). Sex similarities and differences in preferences for short-term mates: What, whether, and why. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 90(3), 468–489.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lichter, D. T. (1990). Delayed marriage, marital homogamy, and the mate selection process among white women. Social Science Quarterly, 71(4), 802–811.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lutz, W., Goujon, A., KC, S., & Sanderson, W. C. (2007). Reconstruction of populations by age, sex and level of educational attainment for 120 countries for 1970–2000. Vienna Yearbook of Population Research, 5, 193–235.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Macy, M. W., & Flache, A. (2009). Social dynamics from the bottom up: Agent-based models of social interaction. In P. Hedström & P. Bearman (Eds.), The Oxford handbook of analytical sociology (pp. 245–268). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mare, R. D. (1991). Five decades of educational assortative mating. American Sociological Review, 56(1), 15–32.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McKinnish, T. G. (2007). Sexually integrated workplaces and divorce: Another form of on-the-job search. The Journal of Human Resources, 42(2), 331–352.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nielsen, H. S., & Svarer, M. (2009). Educational homogamy: How much is opportunities? The Journal of Human Resources, 44(4), 1066–1086.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oppenheimer, V. K. (1977). The sociology of women’s economic role in the family. American Sociological Review, 42(3), 387–406.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oppenheimer, V. K. (1988). A theory of marriage timing. American Journal of Sociology, 94(3), 563–591.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Penke, L., Todd, P. M., Lenton, A. P., & Fasolo, B. (2007). How self-assessments can guide human mating decisions. In G. Geher & G. Miller (Eds.), Mating intelligence: Sex, relationships, and the mind’s reproductive system (pp. 37–75). New York: Psychology Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ruggles, S. (2015). Patriarchy, power, and pay: The tranformation of American families, 1800–2015. Demography, 52(6), 1797–1823.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schmitz, A. (2016). The structure of digital partner choice: A Bourdieusian perspective. Cham: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schoen, R., & Wooldredge, J. (1989). Marriage choices in North Carolina and Virginia, 1969–71 and 1979–81. Journal of Marriage and Family, 51(2), 465–481.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schofer, E., & Meyer, J. W. (2005). The worldwide expansion of higher education in the twentieth century. American Sociological Review, 70(6), 898–920.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schwartz, C. R. (2013). Trends and variation in assortative mating: Causes and consequences. Annual Review of Sociology, 39, 451–470.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schwartz, C. R., & Han, H. (2014). The reversal of the gender gap in education and trends in marital dissolution. American Sociological Review, 79(4), 605–629.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Skopek, J., Schmitz, A., & Blossfeld, H.-P. (2011a). The gendered dynamics of age preferences – Empirical evidence from online dating. Journal of Family Research, 23(3), 267–290.

    Google Scholar 

  • Skopek, J., Schulz, F., & Blossfeld, H.-P. (2011b). Who contacts whom? Educational homophily in online mate selection. European Sociological Review, 27(2), 180–195.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sloman, S., & Sloman, L. (1988). Mate selection in the service of human evolution. Journal of Social and Biological Structures, 11(4), 457–468.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • South, S. J., & Lloyd, K. M. (1992). Marriage opportunities and family formation: Further implications of imbalanced sex ratios. Journal of Marriage and Family, 54(2), 440–451.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • South, S. J., & Lloyd, K. M. (1995). Spousal alternatives and marital dissolution. American Sociological Review, 60(1), 21–35.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • South, S. J., Trent, K., & Shen, Y. (2001). Changing partners: Toward a macrostructural-opportunity theory of marital dissolution. Journal of Marriage and Family, 63(3), 743–754.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sprecher, S. (1986). The relation between inequity and emotions in close relationships. Social Psychology Quarterly, 49(4), 309–321.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sprecher, S. (1992). How men and women expect to feel and behave in response to inequity in close relationships. Social Psychology Quarterly, 55(1), 57–69.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Squazzoni, F. (2012). Agent-based computational sociology. Chichester: Wiley.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Stauder, J. (2006). Die Verfügbarkeit partnerschaftlich gebundener Akteure für den Partnermarkt [The availability of actors with a partner on the partner market]. Kölner Zeitschrift fur Soziologie und Sozialpsychologie, 58(4), 617–637.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Surkyn, J., & Lesthaeghe, R. (2004). Value orientations and the second demographic transition (SDT) in Northern, Western and Southern Europe: An Update. Demographic Research, S3, 45–86.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sweeney, M. M., & Cancian, M. (2004). The changing importance of white women’s economic prospects for assortative mating. Journal of Marriage and Family, 66(4), 1015–1028.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tach, L. (2015). Social mobility in an era of family instability and complexity. The Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science, 657(1), 83–96.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Todd, P. M., Billari, F. C., & Simão, J. (2005). Aggregate age-at-marriage patterns from individual mate-search heuristics. Demography, 42(3), 559–574.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Todd, P. M., Hills, T., & Hendrickson, A. T. (2013). Modeling reproductive decisions with simple heuristics. Demographic Research, 29, 641–661.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Torr, B. M. (2011). The changing relationship between education and marriage in the United States, 1940–2000. Journal of Family History, 36(4), 483–503.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van Bavel, J., & Grow, A. (2016). Introduction: Agent-based modelling as a tool to advance evolutionary population theory. In A. Grow & J. Van Bavel (Eds.), Agent-based modelling in population studies: Concepts, methods, and applications (pp. 3–27). Cham: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Van Bavel, J., & Klesment, M. (2017). Educational pairings, motherhood, and women’s relative earnings in Europe. Demography, 54(6), 2331–2349.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van Bavel, J., Schwartz, C., & Esteve, A. (2018). The reversal of the gender gap in education and its consequences for family life. Annual Review of Sociology, 44, 341–360.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weiss, Y. (1997). The formation and dissolution of families: Why marry? Whom marries whom? And what happens upon divorce? In M. R. Rosenzweig & O. Stark (Eds.), Handbook of population and family economics (pp. 81–123). Amsterdam: Elsevier Science B.V.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Zentner, M., & Eagly, A. H. (2015). A sociocultural framework for understanding partner preferences of women and men: Integration of concepts and evidence. European Review of Social Psychology, 26(1), 328–373.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zentner, M., & Mitura, K. (2012). Stepping out of the caveman’s shadow: Nations’ gender gap predicts degree of sex differentiation in mate preferences. Psychological Science, 23(10), 1176–1185.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

The research leading to these results has received funding from the European Research Council under the European Union’s Seventh Framework Programme (FP/2007-2013)/ERC Grant Agreement no. 312290 for the GENDERBALL project. Eurostat, the European Commission, and the national statistical offices collecting the data have no responsibility for the results and conclusions which were drawn in this paper on the basis of the European Union Statistics on Income and Living Conditions. This paper is partly based on data from Eurostat, European Community Household Panel 1994–2001.The responsibility for all conclusions drawn from the data lies entirely with the authors.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to André Grow .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2019 Springer International Publishing AG, part of Springer Nature

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Grow, A., Van Bavel, J. (2019). Agent-Based Modeling of Family Formation and Dissolution. In: Schoen, R. (eds) Analytical Family Demography. The Springer Series on Demographic Methods and Population Analysis, vol 47. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-93227-9_6

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-93227-9_6

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Cham

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-319-93226-2

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-319-93227-9

  • eBook Packages: Social SciencesSocial Sciences (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics