Skip to main content

Bertrand Meets Ford: Benefits and Losses

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
  • 654 Accesses

Part of the book series: Static & Dynamic Game Theory: Foundations & Applications ((SDGTFA))

Abstract

The paper carries out the detailed comparison of two types of imperfect competition in a general equilibrium model. The price-taking Bertrand competition assumes the myopic income-taking behavior of firms, another type of behavior, price competition under a Ford effect, implies that the firms’ strategic choice takes into account their impact to consumers’ income. Our findings suggest that firms under the Ford effect gather more market power (measured by Lerner index), than “myopic” firms, which is agreed with the folk wisdom “Knowledge is power.” Another folk wisdom implies that increasing of the firms’ market power leads to diminishing in consumers’ well-being (measured by indirect utility.) We show that in general this is not true. We also obtain the sufficient conditions on the representative consumer preference providing the “intuitive” behavior of the indirect utility and show that this condition satisfy the classes of utility functions, which are commonly used as examples (e.g., CES, CARA and HARA.)

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   79.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD   99.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD   99.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Suggesting that if firm profits are tied to local consumption, then firms create an externality by paying high wages: the size of the market for other firms increases with worker wages and wealth, see [12].

  2. 2.

    Note that interpretation of non-integer finite number of oligopolies is totally different from the case of monopolistic competition, where mass of firms is continuum [0, n], thus it does not matter whether n is integer or not. For further interpretational considerations see [13, subsection 4.3].

References

  1. Anderson, J.E., van Wincoop, E.: Trade costs. J. Econ. Lit. 42, 691–751 (2004)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  2. Behrens, K., Murata, Y.: General equilibrium models of monopolistic competition: a new approach. J. Econ. Theory 136, 776–787 (2007)

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  3. Chamberlin, E.: The Theory of Monopolistic Competition. Harvard University Press, Cambridge (1933)

    Google Scholar 

  4. d’Aspremont, C., Dos Santos Ferreira, R.: The Dixit-Stiglitz economy with a ‘small group’ of firms: a simple and robust equilibrium markup formula. Res. Econ. 71(4), 729–739 (2017)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  5. d’Aspremont, C., Dos Santos Ferreira, R., Gerard-Varet, L.: On monopolistic competition and involuntary unemployment. Q. J. Econ. 105(4), 895–919 (1990)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  6. Dhingra, S., Morrow, J.: Monopolistic competition and optimum product diversity under firm heterogeneity. Res. Econ. 71(4), 718–728 (2017)

    Google Scholar 

  7. Ford, H.: My Life and Work. Doubleday, Page, Garden City (1922)

    Google Scholar 

  8. Gabszewicz, J., Vial, J.: Oligopoly à la Cournot in general equilibrium analysis. J. Econ. Theory 4, 381–400 (1972)

    Google Scholar 

  9. Hart, O.: Imperfect competition in general equilibrium: an overview of recent work. In: Arrow, K.J., Honkapohja, S. (eds.) Frontiers in Economics. Basil Blackwell, Oxford (1985)

    Google Scholar 

  10. Magruder, J.R.: Can minimum wage cause a big push? Evidence from Indonesia. J. Dev. Econ. 4(3), 138–166 (2013)

    Google Scholar 

  11. Marschak T., Selten R.: General Equilibrium with Price-Making Firms. Lecture Notes in Economics and Mathematical Systems. Springer, Berlin (1972)

    Google Scholar 

  12. Murphy, K.M., Shleifer, A., Vishny, R.W.: Industrialization and the big push. J. Polit. Econ. 97(5), 1003–1026 (1989)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  13. Parenti, M., Sidorov, A.V., Thisse, J.-F., Zhelobodko, E.V.: Cournot, Bertrand or Chamberlin: toward a reconciliation. Int. J. Econ. Theory 13(1), 29–45 (2017)

    Google Scholar 

  14. Robinson, J.: What is perfect competition? Q. J. Econ. 49, 104–120 (1934)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  15. Taylor, J.E.: Did Henry Ford mean to pay efficiency wages? J. Lab. Res. 24(4), 683–694 (2003)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  16. Vives, X.: Oligopoly Pricing. Old Ideas and New Tools. The MIT Press, Cambridge (2001)

    Google Scholar 

  17. Zhelobodko, E., Kokovin, S., Parenti M., Thisse, J.-F.: Monopolistic competition in general equilibrium: beyond the constant elasticity of substitution. Econometrica 80, 2765–2784 (2012)

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

This work was supported by the Russian Foundation for Basic Researches under grant No.18-010-00728 and by the program of fundamental scientific researches of the SB RAS No. I.5.1, Project No. 0314-2016-0018

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Alexander Sidorov .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendix

Appendix

15.1.1 Proof of Theorem 15.1

Combining Zero-profit condition (15.17) \(m=\frac {f}{L}n=\varphi n\) with formula for symmetric equilibrium demand x = n −1 − φn = (x + φ)−1 we can rewrite the equilibrium mark-up equation for income-taking firms (15.20) as follows

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} \frac{\varphi}{x+\varphi}=\varphi+(1-\varphi)r_{u}(x). \end{aligned}$$

Solving this equation with respect to x we obtain the symmetric equilibrium consumers’ demand x(φ), parametrized by φ = fL, which cannot be represented in closed form for general utility u(x), however, the inverse function φ(x) has the closed-form solution

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} \varphi=\frac{1-x}{2}-\sqrt{\left(\frac{1-x}{2}\right)^{2}-\frac{xr_{u}(x)}{1-r_{u}(x)}}. {} \end{aligned} $$
(15.25)

It was mentioned above that graph of indirect utility V (n) is bell-shaped and equilibrium masses of firms satisfy \(n^*\leq \bar {n}\leq \bar {n}^F\) if and only if \(V'(\bar {n})\leq 0\). Calculating the first derivative V(n) = u(n −1 − φ) − n −1 ⋅ u′(n −1 − φ) and substituting both n = (x + φ)−1 and (15.25) we obtain that

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} n^*\leq \bar{n}\leq \bar{n}^F\iff u(x)\leq\left(\frac{1+x}{2}-\sqrt{\left(\frac{1-x}{2}\right)^{2}-\frac{xr_{u}(x)}{1-r_{u}(x)}}\right)u'(x), \end{aligned}$$

at \(x=\bar {x}\)—the equilibrium consumers demand in case of income-taking firms. The direct calculation shows that this inequality is equivalent to

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} \varDelta_{u}(x)\leq(1-r_{u}(x))\frac{1-x}{2}\left[1-\sqrt{1-\frac{4x r_u(x)}{(1-r_{u}(x))(1-x)^{2}}}\right].{} \end{aligned} $$
(15.26)

We shall prove that this inequality holds for all sufficiently small x > 0, provided that Δ′(0) < r u(0). To do this, consider the following function

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} A_{u}(x)=\frac{x\cdot r_{u}(x)}{1-x}, \end{aligned}$$

which satisfies \(A_{u}(0)=0=\varDelta _{u}(0), \ \varDelta _{u}^{\prime }(0)<A^{\prime }_{u}(0)=r_{u}(0)\). This implies that inequality Δ u(x) ≤ A u(x) holds for all sufficiently small x > 0.

Applying the obvious inequality \(\sqrt {1-z}\leq 1-z/2\) to

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} z=\frac{4x r_u(x)}{(1-r_{u}(x))(1-x)^{2}}, \end{aligned}$$

we obtain that the right-hand side of inequality (15.26)

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} (1-r_{u}(x))\frac{1-x}{2}\left[1-\sqrt{1-\frac{4x r_u(x)}{(1-r_{u}(x))(1-x)^{2}}}\right]\geq A_{u}(x)\geq \varDelta_{u}(x) \end{aligned}$$

for all sufficiently small x > 0, which completes the proof of statement (a).

Applying the similar considerations to Eq. (15.19), which determines the equilibrium markup under a Ford effect, we obtain the following formula for inverse function φ(x)

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} \varphi=\frac{1-r_{u}(x)-x}{2}-\sqrt{\left(\frac{1-r_{u}(x)-x}{2}\right)^{2}-xr_{u}(x)} \end{aligned}$$

Using the similar considerations, we obtain that

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} \bar{n}^{F}\leq n^{*}\iff u(x)\geq\left(\frac{1-r_{u}(x)+x}{2}-\sqrt{\left(\frac{1-r_{u}(x)-x}{2}\right)^{2}-xr_{u}(x)}\right)u'(x) \end{aligned}$$

at \(x=\bar {x}^{F}\)—the equilibrium demand under Bertrand competition with Ford effect. The direct calculation shows that the last inequality is equivalent to

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} \varDelta_{u}(x)\geq\frac{1-r_{u}(x)-x}{2}\left[1-\sqrt{1-\frac{4xr_{u}(x)}{\left(1-r_{u}(x)-x\right)^{2}}}\right].{} \end{aligned} $$
(15.27)

Now assume

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} \delta_{u}>\frac{r_{u}(0)}{1-r_{u}(0)}, \end{aligned}$$

which implies that

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} \alpha\equiv\frac{r_{u}(0)+(1-r_{u}(0))\delta_{u}}{2r_{u}(0)}>1. \end{aligned}$$

Let

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} B_{u}(x)\equiv \frac{\alpha xr_{u}(x)}{1-r_{u}(x)-x}, \end{aligned}$$

it is obvious that Δ u(0) = B u(0) = 0, and

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} B^{\prime}_{u}(0)=\frac{\alpha r_{u}(0)}{1-r_{u}(0)}=\frac{r_{u}(0)+(1-r_{u}(0))\delta_{u}}{2(1-r_{u}(0))}<\delta_{u}=\varDelta^{\prime}_u(0), \end{aligned}$$

which implies that inequality Δ u(x) ≥ B u(x) holds for all sufficiently small x.

On the other hand, the inequality \(\sqrt {1-z}\geq 1-\alpha z/2\) obviously holds for any given α > 1 and \(z\in \left [0,\frac {4(\alpha -1)}{\alpha ^{2}}\right ]\). Applying this inequality to

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} z=\frac{4xr_{u}(x)}{\left(1-r_{u}(x)-x\right)^{2}}, \alpha=\frac{r_{u}(0)+(1-r_{u}(0))\delta_{u}}{2r_{u}(0)}, \end{aligned}$$

we obtain that the right-hand side of (15.27) satisfies

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} \frac{1-r_{u}(x)-x}{2}\left[1-\sqrt{1-\frac{4xr_{u}(x)}{\left(1-r_{u}(x)-x\right)^{2}}}\right]\leq B_{u}(x){} \end{aligned} $$
(15.28)

for all sufficiently small x > 0, because x → 0 implies z → 0. This completes the proof of Theorem 15.1.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2018 Springer International Publishing AG, part of Springer Nature

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Sidorov, A., Parenti, M., Thisse, JF. (2018). Bertrand Meets Ford: Benefits and Losses. In: Petrosyan, L., Mazalov, V., Zenkevich, N. (eds) Frontiers of Dynamic Games. Static & Dynamic Game Theory: Foundations & Applications. Birkhäuser, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-92988-0_15

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics